Author(s): | Eltis, David |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Hogendorn, Jan |
Published by EH.NET (July 1, 2000)
David Eltis, The Rise of African Slavery in the Americas, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 2000. xvii + 353 pp., $59.95 (cloth), ISBN:
0-521-65231-6.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Jan Hogendorn, Department of Economics, Colby College.
David Eltis of Queen’s University, Canada, has produced an ambitious
explanatory survey on the emergence of African slavery in the Americas. Why, he
asks, should a slave system have arisen in the New World under western European
auspices when the countries involved were in so many other ways leaders in
developing political and economic freedoms?
Eltis explores the issue in a lengthy, densely-written volume that serves to
highlight three decades of advance in the study of American slavery and the
Atlantic slave trade, an intellectual progress in which he has been a major
player. A significant innovation in this book is the way it integrates analyses
of labor and commodity markets in Africa, Europe, and the Americas with
transport costs to arrive at conclusions based broadly on demand and supply.
Any attempt to achieve such breadth is a daunting task with the danger that the
thread of the argument will be lost, but Eltis has succeeded in making his
story plausible and coherent — though not an easy read.
The first analytical chapter (Chapter 2) undertakes to show the relationship
between the rise of the Atlantic slave trade and the development of a free
labor market and modern labor force in Europe. Here the focus is on how the
competing demands for labor on both sides of the Atlantic together with
improvement in the position of labor in Europe put limits on the labor supply
in the Americas, giving the necessary opening for African slavery to emerge in
that area.
In Chapter 3, “Europeans and African Slavery in the Americas,” Eltis turns to
the question of why European slaves were not an adequate substitute for
Africans in bondage. He notes that military captives and criminals were
available in quantity and reminds us (in interesting detail) of the long
tradition of galley slaves at the oars of Mediterranean shipping. But in this
case the implicit debate on who was eligible for slavery, who an insider and
who an outsider, the balance went against the use of European slaves — a
decision made the easier by the availability of African slaves. He continues
the analysis into issues of gender, probing why women were far more important
in the African slave trade than they were among other migrant flows of labor
indentured and free. The position of European women in the eyes of the
Europeans themselves was a cultural norm that kept them from plantation gang
labor but such norms did not protect African women.
These basically cultural explanations become more explicitly economic in
Chapter 5, on productivity in the slave trade. In his treatment Eltis
emphasizes the role of transport costs. The focus is apt because as he points
out the high cost of organization, financing, shipping, handling, and insurance
together with the long delays often experienced in trading on the African
coasts raised the price of both imports of goods to Africa and slaves exported
from that continent to about double their respective prices at the source. The
slave trade was “possibly the most international activity of the pre-industrial
era” (p. 136), with huge transport bills for the assembly of the goods shipped
from Europe and Asia (with textiles from India a major method of paying for
slaves), for transporting these goods to Africa, and then for the movement of
slaves to the New World.
At about the halfway point of the book, the focus shifts to Africa and the
supply side. The first question of Chapter 6 is why European enterprise
resulted in a movement of labor to the Americas when the same commodities could
have been produced by Europeans in Africa itself. An interesting review of
European attempts to establish farms and plantations on or near the African
coast leads to analysis of technical and ecological constraints but concludes
that the main barriers were political and military, with Europeans generally
unable at this stage to penetrate any significant distance inland from their
ships’ guns. So with commodity production in Africa foreclosed but possible
across the Atlantic, the most profitable alternative was to deal with African
suppliers of slaves. The establishment of these contacts and their
productivity-enhancing improvement concludes this chapter. An absorbing thread
of this discussion and that of the following chapter, “The African Impact on
the Transatlantic Slave Trade,” is how the trans-Atlantic shippers had to
confront resistance by slaves who, particularly at or near the coast, often
attempted to seize their floating prisons and escape. Eltis concludes that in
spite of the many productivity-increasing improvements in transport, one
economic fact of life was that costs of policing this risk were much higher
than otherwise. The main impact was on labor costs, where, he estimates,
outlays were higher by about two-thirds compared to a situation where policing
was not necessary. The effect of these higher costs was to reduce the quantity
of slaves exported by nearly ten percent, or about half a million people,
between 1700 and 1800, but as he notes, the extent of such resistance was very
different from one coastal location to another.
Another feature of the chapter on the “African Impact” is the description of
the complicated task facing European shippers of wares that had to be tailored
to the variegated demand patterns along the coast. The differences in demand
were striking, certainly not indicative of homogenized tastes. For example, in
1662-1703 according to Royal African Company records, imports of textiles to
the Bight of Biafra were 1 percent of all RAC shipments compared to 77 percent
along the Gold Coast; while for the same two areas metals were respectively 80
percent and 6 percent of total shipments. Almost all of the RAC’s cowries went
to the Slave Coast, with few arriving at any other destination. By commodity,
rarely did the average percentage share for the coast as a whole reflect the
percentage for any single one of the five regions shown in the data.
The volume concludes with chapters providing a comparative perspective on the
English plantations in America, on ethnicity in the trade, on the ultimate
impact of the trade on Europe, and with three appendices (on age and sex of the
Africans shipped to American bondage, on slave prices, and on the merchandise
imports to West Africa that served to purchase slaves).
Overall, Eltis’s impressive book does good work in two different arenas.
Specialists in research on the Atlantic slave trade and slavery in Africa and
the Americas will see better than before the integration among markets and
regions that characterized this trade. Economists and historians who are not
specialists will see this as well, but they will also find the book a
proficient and well-sourced overview of a massive subject.
Jan Hogendorn is the Grossman Professor of Economics at Colby College and the
author (with Paul Lovejoy) of Slow Death for Slavery: The Course of
Abolition in Northern Nigeria, 1897-1936, Cambridge University Press 1993.
Subject(s): | Servitude and Slavery |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 18th Century |