Author(s): | Wright, Robert E. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Perkins, Edwin J. |
Published by EH.NET (November 2001)
Robert E. Wright, The Origins of Commercial Banking in America,
1750-1800. London and New York: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2001. xii
+ 219 pp. $65 (cloth), ISBN: 0-7425-2086-2; $24.95 (paperback), ISBN:
0-7425-2087-0.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Edwin J. Perkins, Professor of History, emeritus,
University of Southern California.
Robert Wright has written a highly original book that merits our attention.
First, he overlaps the late colonial period and the first decade of the early
national era — an uncommon periodization for financial historians. Previous
authors typically have covered either the colonial period or the national
period, not both. Second, Wright approaches the subject mainly from an
economic perspective rather than from a political angle. Earlier writers have
been mostly concerned with the public policy ramifications of legislative
debates over financial matters, and they have been less concerned with the
impact of financial legislation on the economy. Trained as a historian but
employed for several years in the economics department of the University of
Virginia, Wright has a unique academic profile. That interdisciplinary
background has enabled him to generate an analysis of critical financial
issues during this era that is unmatched by any of his predecessors. For
economists, in particular, this volume stands as the new starting point for
gaining an understanding of the evolution of U.S. commercial banking.
Wright focuses throughout on the perpetual demand for improved liquidity. The
colonial economy had no active private banks. Likewise, there was no uniform
currency since the British had forbidden the establishment of a colonial mint.
As a result, most of the coinage in circulation originated in Spain’s colonial
empire in the Western Hemisphere. The paper currency issues of the various
colonial legislatures supplemented these hard monies. Capital markets in the
colonies were non-existent or thin. Only Massachusetts had a public debt that
was privately held and occasionally traded. The whole financial system was
institutionally immature. A huge percentage of the outstanding colonial
mercantile debt could be traced back to the London money market. Colonial
merchants did make use of domestic and foreign bills of exchange, but it was
nearly impossible to convert these financial instruments into cash during
periods of stringency. While the financial system was sufficiently functional
to support steady increases in the size of the colonial economy (primarily due
to population growth), its overall performance was less than optimal.
Liquidity was sorely lacking. Merchants, family farmers, great planters, and
artisans all sought some form of institutional relief.
Parliamentary regulations and the negative attitudes of distant British
administrators who were responsible for colonial affairs discouraged private
initiatives. Colonial leaders from South Carolina to New England periodically
sought legislative permission to create banks of one variety or another, but
none of these attempts produced anything sustainable. Wright covers these
early efforts in a fair amount of detail. He views these abortive efforts as
legitimate antecedents of the private commercial banks that emerged after
1780.
After the achievement of independence, the new nation began to experiment with
modern commercial banking. Luckily, these experiments, which aroused much
public debate and legislative controversy at the state and federal levels,
almost immediately led to the creation of viable institutions. I say “luckily”
because the effort to create similar institutions in many other emerging
nations over the last two centuries has produced numerous tragic missteps.
The Bank of North America, the brainchild of Robert Morris, the famous
treasurer of the confederation government, became the prime model for all
subsequent commercial banks. It issued currency supported by adequate specie
reserves, accepted deposits, discounted mercantile notes, and turned a
respectable profit for investors. Other commercial banks operating under state
charters began to multiply. The problem of illiquidity in the U.S. economy was
steadily alleviated thereafter. The national government created the Bank of
the United States, which was the largest economic unit in the economy
throughout its twenty-year life span. Commercial banks were the pillars and
catalysts for the expansion of the U.S. economy from 1790 forward. We are
finally coming to the realization, thanks largely to the contributions of
Richard Sylla and his collaborators, that improvements in financial services
preceded advancements in agriculture, transportation, and industry.
For his discussion of events after 1780, Wright draws most of his information
from a careful analysis of banking in Pennsylvania and New York. His
conclusions contrast at many points with Naomi Lamoreaux’s study of New
England banking during the same period. In her research, Lamoreaux found that
commercial banks were typically closely held; the major investors dominated
the board of directors and made numerous insider loans to themselves. Wright
has found a different pattern in the middle Atlantic region. These banks had a
larger capitalization and a broader ownership. They made loans mainly to
depositors, not owners, and the occupations of borrowers varied — from
merchants to farmers to artisans. As much as I admire Wright’s detailed
discussion of the development of the commercial banking system, I would have
gone about this project in a different manner — not necessarily better, but
different and complementary. Since I have been working in this subfield for
decades, I offer my own admittedly biased opinions without apology.
Whereas Wright concentrates on the demand for liquidity, I would have
celebrated the supply side of the equation. I am not convinced that the
colonial demand for liquidity was any different than the persistent demands of
thousands of urban merchants in past civilizations. I take the demand for
superior financial services as a given — a truism. What was astonishingly
different in the eighteenth century was the institutional response in the new
United States. Borrowing piecemeal from the example of a handful of British
private bankers and the singular Bank of England, the first generation of
independent Americans were imaginative and prudent institutional innovators.
Despite their strategic differences, Hamiltonians and Jeffersonians both
wanted a successful financial system — if only to prove to a skeptical world
that a republican form of government could survive and indeed thrive
financially as well as politically.
I also wish Wright had cited the public loan offices created by the colonial
legislatures as the prime forerunners of the modern commercial bank. Across
the Atlantic Ocean, advocates of land banks had tried for centuries to gain
the attention and approval of the ruling classes. Their proposed land banks
were designed to offer loans to citizens with real estate as collateral. None
of these European schemes proved viable. But in English North America, land
banks in the middle colonies (but not in New England) operated successfully
for decades. They made loans to a wide swath of landholders; they experienced
few losses; and they generated substantial interest revenue for their
provincial legislatures. Their issues of paper currency were retired at their
original purchasing-power values; depreciation was not a serious problem. The
Pennsylvania legislature imposed no new taxes for decades because interest
income from the loan office covered its modest annual expenses. True, the loan
offices did not accept deposits and did not discount mercantile paper, but
they succeeded over a long period of time, whereas similar efforts in all
other contemporary societies had failed. The colonial land offices were
remarkable enterprises for their era and deserve more recognition as emulative
institutional models.
My third friendly amendment relates to the coverage of the Bank of the United
States. Wright just does not devote sufficient space to this novel
institution. It too was highly innovative. Unlike the Bank of England, its
main customers after 1795 were private citizens, not governments. It possessed
branch offices in major port cities. As David Cowen has recently argued, the
BUS in tandem with the U.S. Treasury Department acted very much like a modern
central bank. Fourthly, Wright might have cited the recent work of Glenn
Crothers on commercial banking in northern Virginia in the 1790s. I had better
stop here with my recommended additions or I might be roundly accused of
criticizing the author for not writing the book I had envisioned rather than
the book he chose to write. By revising the analytical model for all subsequent
historians who embark on an examination of the origins of U.S. commercial
banking, Robert Wright has made a major scholarly contribution. The supply
side innovations did not occur in a vacuum, Wright reminds us; they came about
because thousands of participants in the eighteenth-century economy desired
increased levels of liquidity. If the author has gone slightly overboard to
prove a valid point, he has done so in a noble cause.
Edwin J. Perkins has written extensively about financial history. His books
include American Public Finance and Financial Services, 1700-1815 (Ohio
State University Press, 1994). His most recent publication is Wall Street
to Main Street: Charles Merrill and Middle Class Investors (Cambridge
University Press, 1999).
Subject(s): | Financial Markets, Financial Institutions, and Monetary History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 18th Century |