EH.net is owned and operated by the Economic History Association
with the support of other sponsoring organizations.

The Idea of Capitalism before the Industrial Revolution

Author(s):Grassby, Richard
Reviewer(s):Teichgraeber, Richard F.

Published by EH.NET (June 1, 2000)

Richard Grassby, The Idea of Capitalism before the Industrial

Revolution. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 1999. ix + 145 pp. $50.00

(cloth), $14.95 (paper), ISBN: 0-847-69362-1 (cloth), 0-8476-9633-2 (paper).

Reviewed for EH.NET by Richard F. Teichgraeber III, Murphy Institute of

Political Economy and Department of History, Tulane University.

This book appears at a time when the bloody struggle between capitalism and

socialism unexpectedly seems to have ended, and now we must wonder why

capitalism triumphed and where it is leading us. Yet Richard Grassby, who has

written several books on the economic and social history of early-modern

England, and is currently a member of the Institute for Advanced Study,

suggests almost all our talk of the triumph of capitalism is mistaken.

Investigating the origins and evolution of the term, he reminds us that

“capitalism” did not exist as a distinct idea before the Industrial Revolution,

and that it first gained prominence only at the turn of the last century as

“the essential Manichean bogeyman of socialist theory” (p. 68). Since then,

“capitalism” has been revised and expanded in various ways to provide

explanations for innovations in almost every field of modern human activity.

The result, according to Grassby, is an idea that retains some symbolic

importance but little historical reality or explanatory power. “When we try to

understand the modern world,” he concludes, ” the idea of capitalism

constitutes the problem, not the solution” (p. 61).

Grassby’s insistence that even the most refined models of capitalism fail to

account for how change takes place over time should sound familiar to

specialists who know the economic and social history of pre-industrial Europe.

In fact, many historians have shared Grassby’s doubts about the explanatory

power of capitalism, and his argument perhaps would have been stronger had he

directly enlisted their support, rather than assembling a familiar inventory of

ambiguities and inconsistencies that color the work of those who have refused

to heed the call to cut the term “capitalism” from their vocabulary.

Readers more interested in understanding where capitalism, currently unchecked

by any substantial opposition and giddy with self-congratulation, may be taking

us, will find that Grassby has disappointingly little to say. Although we are

told his book will explore the influence of this still powerful idea on the

formation of the world in which we live, the issue is never directly or

systematically addressed. Those who recall Andrew Shonfield’s brief yet

persuasive justification for the continued use of the word “capitalism” — “no

one, not even its severest critics, has proposed a better word to put in its

place” — are not likely to be swayed by anything Grassby says. (Andrew

Shonfield, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private

Power, Oxford University Press, 1965, p. 3.) For in rehearsing the complex

and contested history of the word, he too offers nothing to take its place.

That the biggest questions in history often seem intractable is no

breath-taking insight. What is capitalism? How has it changed over time? Can

various conceptions of capitalism be unified? Grassby has raised these

questions, however, not to open them to further inquiry, so much as to dismiss

them out of hand. He, perhaps, could have addressed them more helpfully by

beginning with a query of a different order, and one that can be answered: “Why

must capitalism constitute the central problem in any effort to understand the

modern world?”

Richard F. Teichgraeber III is author of ‘Free Trade’ and Moral Philosophy:

Rethinking the Sources of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations (Duke University

Press, 1986).

Subject(s):History of Economic Thought; Methodology
Geographic Area(s):Europe
Time Period(s):18th Century