Author(s): | Gelpi, Rosa-Maria Julien-Labruyère, François Ju |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Calder, Lendol G. |
Published by EH.NET (August 2000)
Rosa-Maria Gelpi and Fran?ois Julien-Labruy?re, The History of Consumer
Credit: Doctrines and Practices. Translated by Mn Liam Gavin. New York: St.
Martin’s Press, 2000. xx + 190 pp. $59.95 (hardbound), ISBN 0-312-22415-X.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Lendol G. Calder, Department of History, Augustana
College, Rock Island, IL.
Is credit good for us? Dante didn’t think so. In his Inferno, we find usurers
consigned to the seventh circle of hell, doomed to “roam round and round” among
their fellow inmates, the blasphemers, murderers, sodomites, and others who
practiced violence against God and nature. Dante doesn’t say so, but he leaves
us free to speculate that moneylenders continue to practice their trade in
hell, lending money at interest to the damned. If so, it would make Visa’s
claim to be “everywhere you want to be” seem a little too modest! But enough of
this credit bashing, plead the authors of this little volume on the history of
consumer credit. According to Rosa-Maria Gelpi and Fran?ois Julien-Labruy?re,
credit is too often made to be a scapegoat during times of social and economic
crises, so that even today when we look more kindly on credit than Dante,
consumer credit continues to be blamed for everything from business recessions
to personal bankruptcies to society’s moral degeneracy. It’s enormously unfair,
argue Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re, who invite us to accompany them on a “stroll
through history” that will reveal just how good credit really is for us. As
“the cornerstone” of economic growth (p. 84), as “one of the greatest promoters
of social mobility” (p. 171), and as the “single greatest factor of social
integration” (p. 95), they conclude that consumer credit is one of the most
reliable indicators of advanced civilization, if not an important cause of it.
But if all this is true, why has consumer credit had to battle so hard and so
long against a shameful stigma of wastefulness and wrongdoing to achieve a
moral and economic legitimacy? Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re present their history
as a search for the origins of the cloud of bad feeling that surround this most
crucial institution of modern consumer societies. The crux of their argument is
that present day attitudes about credit-attitudes rarely stated as propositions
but that operate instead as a “mute yet active unconscious”-are outmoded and
debilitating “hangovers” from an earlier era in the history of western
societies, an era when social practices were inspired by theology and ethics
rather than by the economy of free markets, as they increasingly are today. In
other words, consumer credit struggles against a massive case of “cultural
lag.” The volume’s subtitle-“Doctrines and Practices”-neatly summarizes the
tale told in this book. Through the sixteenth century and beyond, legions of
shortsighted theologians and philosophers tried to strangle credit in the noose
of religious dogma, with the end result that credit was “more or less forbidden
but more or less practiced because more or less necessary” (p. 95). But since
the Reformation and Enlightenment, and primarily through the shining example of
the Americans, religious doctrine has been replaced by economic practice as our
fundamental social gyroscope, so that lending and borrowing are increasingly
viewed more properly as economic concepts, free of unnecessary moral baggage.
Today, in societies where economic “practice” is given primacy over moral and
religious “doctrines,” a bright future is being built on the basis of economic
growth, responsible household budgeting and greater “self-actualization”
through credit-financed consumption.
If all this sounds like a textbook case of the “Whig interpretation of
history,” well, it is, though of a refined and smartly written sort. Both
authors are high-ranking officers for Cetelem, the French personal finance
company that over the last five decades has worked to modernize European
household credit on an American model (Gelpi is also Professor of Economics at
the Free University of Lille). Given their day jobs, the authors’ spirited
defense of consumer credit is hardly surprising. Of the criticism of credit
there is no end, which means that Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re are following a
well-worn path blazed in the United States in the 1930s by the economist Morris
Neifeld, who worked as a credit analyst for Beneficial. Neifeld, whose
Personal Finance Comes of Age (1939) resembles the work under review
here, labored tirelessly though his writings to elevate the status of his
profession. But in terms of eloquence and wit, The History of Consumer
Credit sets a new standard for defenses of consumer credit.
Still, glorifying the present at the expense of the past has its costs, and
they are manifest here. The biggest problem is that the authors never really
succeed in helping us to understand why so many otherwise smart people-from
Aristotle to Ezra Pound-opposed on principle the lending of money at interest,
or why their ideas resonated so long in the public mind. Consider the treatment
given to John Calvin, himself an innovator when it came to new thinking about
credit: “[Calvin’s] work consisted in giving a new faith to the classes who,
through their social skills, were destined to dominate the future. This
supposes a relatively advanced economic organization, and Calvin built his
moral system on such an organization” (p. 50). A page later, we are told, “For
Calvin, the only good deed was worldly success” (p. 51). Reductiveness on this
scale is not easy; one has to work hard at it. When every person and system of
belief is viewed through the narrow lens of what is good for the development of
credit, when economic progress and “social integration” into the wonders of
consumerism are the only ends that count, it becomes impossible to understand
what all the fuss over usury was really about.
If the history is whiggish, it is also mostly recycled, at least through the
first eight chapters. Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re begin their story in
Mesopotamia, where the Code of Hammurabi (1792-1750 BC) established the first
known law defining and regulating usury. Moving briskly on, they describe the
business of credit in ancient Greece, the Roman Empire, Gothic Catalonia (where
we see the first documented case of a European pawnbroker, 1000 AD), medieval
Italy (which established the first public pawnshops, known as monts-de-pi?t?s,
in the fifteenth century), northern Europe at the time of the Reformation, and
the United States, whose experience is “central” to the history of consumer
credit because, beginning in the nineteenth century, it “offered to build the
future” on the installment plan. Based on standard secondary sources, this part
of the story involves a familiar cast of villains and heroes. Among those who
come off looking particularly stupid or close-minded is Aristotle, who,
declaring money to be sterile, decried interest as being a revolt against
nature (silly old Aristotle, who “has only value judgments to offer when it
comes to economics” (p. 8). Other villains in this tale include the Hebrews,
the first people to condemn interest-bearing loans; the Church Fathers,
especially Saint Basil, who began more than 1000 years of a total ban on
interest by the Church; Charlemagne, who declared the first secular bans on
usury; Dante, of course; the Inquisition at the time of the Councils of Lyon
(1274) and Vienne (1312); and Catholic Europe after the Reformation, which
doomed southern Europe to centuries of economic decadence, thereby offering “a
lesson in how to fail to modernize an economy, while retaining one’s guilt
feelings!” (p. 66)
Opposed to this deadwood are the heroes of modern credit, men who were smart
enough to see through Aristotle and brave enough to relativize the Scriptural
prohibitions against interest, recognizing that a new type of economy was
coming into being where wealth was created, not just plundered or commandeered.
These include Scholastic theologians such as Thomas Aquinas, the Reformers
Luther and Calvin, and greatest of all, Enlightenment champions of reason and
liberty such as Jeremy Bentham and Anne Robert Jacques Turgot. Lengthy
quotations from the latter two figures are included in the text, as Gelpi and
Julien-Labruy?re recommend that all who are interested in contemporary debates
over consumer credit can do no better than to read Bentham’s Defense of
Usury (1787) and Turgot’s Memoir (1770), which will persuade
clear-thinking persons that the strict regulation of credit markets hurt the
poor most of all while making criminals of everyone else.
Beyond the assertive and lively prose (which is marred in this English edition
by a poor job of copy editing that allows too many misspellings and missing
words), the strength of this book lies in the final two chapters. It is only
recently that consumer credit has begun to receive from historians the
attention it deserves. Part of the reason for this is that credit is a commerce
deeply cloaked in confidentiality (as Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re point out,
until recently the guiding principle of public relations for lenders was “to
live happily you must live in secret”). What Gelpi and Julien-Labruy?re bring
to the history of consumer credit is valuable insiders’ knowledge about the
credit business in Europe over the last hundred years. Much of this information
is interesting and new. For example, I was surprised to learn just how closely
the European development of consumer credit has mirrored the history of credit
in the United States, though with significant time lags between countries.
Great Britain passed its first laws affecting consumer credit in the late
nineteenth century, while Italy only did so in 1992!
This book seems to have been written primarily to influence the opinions of
European policymakers in Brussels, who the authors would like to see taking a
hands off approach to credit markets so governments can treat the causes of
economic woes (e.g., high taxes, low investment) rather than mere symptoms
(e.g., overindebtedness). This is a defensible wish, but there are risks
involved when looking for a usable past, risks the authors seem unaware of.
When packaged with facile claims such as this-“A healthy morality always
coincides with commercial wisdom” (p. 55)-or with shaky historical claims such
as this-“The history of consumer credit in the United States is almost entirely
free of historic influences” (p. 119)-some readers will find even the credible
claims in this book rather suspect.
Lendol Calder, author of Financing the American Dream: A Cultural History
of Consumer Credit (Princeton University Press, 1999) is assistant
professor of history at Augustana College and a Carnegie Scholar with the
Carnegie Academy for the Scholarship of Teaching and Learning.
Subject(s): | Household, Family and Consumer History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | General, International, or Comparative |
Time Period(s): | General or Comparative |