Author(s): | Hall, Thomas E. Ferguson, David J. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Wicker, Elmus |
Published by EH.NET (November 1998)
Thomas E. Hall and J. David Ferguson, The Great Depression: An International
Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies, Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press. 1998, Pp. xvii + 194, pp. $42.50 (cloth),
ISBN: 0-472-09667-2.
Reviewed for EH NET by Elmus Wicker, Dept. of Economics, Indiana University.
The authors assert that they wrote this book for two reasons:
disillusionment with how macroeconomics is taught at the college level and a
commitment to the Friedman and Schwartz interpretation of the Great
Depression that the Federal Reserve was an “incredible source of policy
errors.” From the first assertion, I infer that the audience for this book is
primarily college students, though I think it deserves a wider
readership among the economically literate. From the second assertion, I
infer that they believe that policymakers had the knowledge to have acted
differently. However, at no point do the authors make a serious effort to
defend that presumption. I will illustrate their neglect with several
crucial examples further on.
The book makes no pretence at being a contribution to our knowledge of the
Great Depression and can not be judged by such a narrow criterion. It must be
appraised by a different standard; that is, how well the authors pose the
major questions that must be answered and the skill and judiciousness with
which they evaluate the current state of our
knowledge of the Great Depression, given the audience to which the book
is addressed. Lester Chandler’s America’s Greatest Depression,
1929-1941 (New York: Harper and Row, 1970) is the only competitor
that immediately comes to mind, but Chandler’s purpose was not to assess the
current state of our knowledge of the Great Depression but to describe
what happened. Nevertheless, the audience is apparently the same.
Although the authors stress that the Great Depression was a global event
and not simply a U.S. debacle, the emphasis remains on what happened in the
United States. For example, output and unemployment in the
rest-of-the-world, excluding the U.S. and two European countries, is not
described. Hall and
Ferguson follow the current fad of placing the gold standard as the central
focal point. But what they and others have not done is to show specifically
how the gold standard was causally significant for the Great Depression in the
U.S.. Gold standard considerations played a very minor role, if they played
any role at all, in the decision of the New York Fed to advance the
discount rate in 1931; moreover, the bank failure rate had accelerated two
and one-half weeks before the discount rate was advanced. Only three of
the thirteen chapters address foreign country issues. France, Germany, and
Great Britain are treated in chapter 4, economic recovery in Germany in
chapter 10, and the world financial crisis in chapter 7. The
reader can easily come away with the view that what was truly significant
occurred in the U.S. and a few European countries and not in the
rest-of-the-world.
The Friedman and Schwartz influence is apparent in at least two important
respects:
the overarching significance accorded the behavior of the money stock and
the negative assessment of the behavior of the policymakers,
neither of which is critically evaluated. If the jury is still out on the
money-income causal nexus, the burden of the historical evidence is too
great to warrant any conclusion about the Fed’s ineptness.
What is absolutely crucial to appraising the performance of Fed officials is
to know the extent of their knowledge of the determinants
of the money stock. Whether or not they could have offset the increase in the
currency-deposit ratio turns on what they knew or did not know about the
role of the C/D and R/D ratios as determinants of the money stock. The authors
set out the modern textbook version of the determinants of M:
M = {(1 + cd)/(cd + rd)}B but they say nothing
about the origins of that equation. The currency-deposit ratio was
not fully modeled until 1933 in a pair of articles
by James Harvey Rogers (“The Absorption of Bank Credit.”
Econometrica, 1933, Vol. l, 63-70) and by James Angell and Karel
Ficek
(“The Expansion of Bank Credit,” Journal of Political Economy, 1933,
Vol.
41, 1-31 and 152-93). Rogers’ formal
framework had appeared in an earlier book, Stock Speculation and the
Money Market, (Lucas Brothers: Columbia,
Missouri, 1927, pp. 53-62) which was completely ignored by the economics
profession. Less formally, Benjamin Strong, Governor of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, introduced the currency-deposit
ratio in the Stabilization Hearings in 1926 (Benjamin Strong, Hearings
Before the Committee of Banking and Currency, House of Representatives,
1926, 69th Congress, parts 1-2, 334-5 and 422) and even earlier in The Report
of the Joint Committee of Agricultural Inquiry in 1922 (Agricultural
Inquiry: Hearings Before the Joint Commission of Agricultural Inquiry, 1922,
64th
Congress. 1st Session). Although Strong’s testimony includes a simple
expansion process with a C/D ratio, this is by itself a mighty thin reed on
which to hold the Federal Reserve System accountable for not forestalling a
decline in the money stock between 1929 and 1933. Neither Friedman and
Schwartz nor Hall and Ferguson have demonstrated that knowledge of the
determinants of the money stock was available to Fed officials. In its
absence the case for the Fed’s ineptness collapses.
Friedman and Schwartz have made a distinguished contribution to our
understanding of the Great Depression, but Hall and Ferguson’s uncritical
acceptance of some of their historical interpretations of particular
episodes reveals a lack of acquaintance with more recent contributions
. For example, the authors repeat and apparently accept the Friedman and
Schwartz view that had Benjamin Strong lived Fed policy would have been
better. But that is no longer a defensible hypothesis. The Fed did in 1930
exactly what it had done in
1924 and 1927–that is reduce the indebtedness of the New York Fed to $50
million. It worked in 1924 and 1927; it did not work in 1930! Moreover,
there are no defensible grounds for criticizing the Fed’s behavior for
ignoring the demand for excess reserves when raising reserve requirements in
1936 and 1937. I know of no American economist who had any knowledge of a
demand for excess reserves.
In attempting to explain the slow recovery from the Great Depression, the
authors pay no attention at all to Michael Darby’s unemployment estimates
(“Three and a Half Million Employees Have Been Mislaid: An Explanation of
Unemployment, 1934-1941,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84,
1-16).
He maintained that the slow recovery from 1934 to
1941 was a fiction–there was a strong movement toward the natural rate after
1935. There are good reasons to question Darby’s estimates, but no good
reasons for completely ignoring them.
Hall and Ferguson appear to be carried away with their negative assessment of
Fed policymakers. At one point they refer to the camps of the
unemployed and destitute peoples as “Federalreservevilles” instead of
“Hoovervilles”. Neither appellation is apt. It is obvious that both go far
beyond what either the historical of statistical evidence warrants. The tone
is stridently judgmental.
The book may very well succeed in
rejuvenating moribund students who are
trying to master macroeconomics, but the authors fail to present a
convincing case that Fed policy was an “incredible sequence of policy
errors.”
Elmus Wicker Department of Economics Indiana University
Elmus Wicker is Professor of Economics, Emeritus at Indiana University. He is
the author of Banking Panics of
the Great Depression, Cambridge University Press. 1996, and has
recently completed a manuscript titled
Banking Panics of the National Banking Era.
Subject(s): | Financial Markets, Financial Institutions, and Monetary History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: Pre WWII |