Author(s): | Pryor, Frederic L. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Higgs, Robert |
Published by EH.NET (October 2002)
Frederic L. Pryor, The Future of U.S. Capitalism. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2002. xiii + 447 pp. $35 (hardback), ISBN: 0-521-81358-1.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Robert Higgs, The Independent Institute.
The Future of U.S. Capitalism, by Frederic L. Pryor, is an odd book,
and I doubt that many economic historians will find it useful, either in
research or in teaching. Pryor’s objective in the book is to forecast the
future development of various economic, social, and political aspects of U.S.
“capitalism.” (His choice of terms would not be mine. In my view, anything
properly described as capitalism in the United States came to an end no later
than 1933. To retain the term “capitalism” contributes to misunderstandings of
how a predominantly market-oriented system works, and thereby fosters further
inroads into what little remains of the market system.) In Pryor’s own words,
he intends to consider: “What have been the key trends in the U.S. economic
system in the second half of the twentieth century and what causes underlay
them? If current trends will not continue, what will replace them, and why? At
what points do we lack sufficient knowledge, either theoretical or factual, to
make responsible predictions about the future?” (p. 1).
After an introductory chapter, the author considers “internal influences on the
economic system,” with chapters on saving and economic growth, economic
fluctuations and financial crises, economic inequality, and globalization. Next
he takes up “external influences on the economic system,” with chapters on
natural resources and the environment, social factors, and political factors. A
final set of chapters deals with “changes in crucial economic institutions and
organizations,” giving attention to the evolution of business enterprises,
market competition, government regulation and ownership, and government
spending. The conclusion considers, “Whither U.S. Capitalism?” Besides
including more than thirty pages of appendices on data and statistical
relationships, the author directs the interested reader to an extensive
collection of “external appendices and accompanying tables and charts” that can
be viewed at his web site.
Pryor declares that the book “is not about the economy per se” (p. 2) but
“about the institutions and organizations through which economic activity is
channeled. [I]t is an exercise in positive, not normative, economics” (p. 3). A
reader who expects to find an analysis deeply informed by the new institutional
economics, however, will be disappointed. No coherent overarching theory or
model guides the analysis. Instead, Pryor calls on various theoretical
rationales in an ad hoc manner as he proceeds from one topic to another. A
great deal of the econometric analysis amounts to little more than data mining.
On the spectrum from optimism to pessimism, Pryor definitely stands closer to
the darker terminus, concluding that “the U.S. economic system faces some very
serious problems in the coming decades” (p. 23).
No brief review can even list all the specific issues Pryor considers in this
book. Suffice to say, he takes up hundreds of separate matters large and small,
spends considerable time assessing data problems, and presents countless
regression equations as well as many tables, graphs, and charts. His analysis
is, if anything, data-intensive, a reflection no doubt of his seeming faith
that if we crunch enough numbers, we will put ourselves in a position to
forecast future developments accurately. Time and again, however, he finds
himself immersed in a “welter of conflicting results” (p. 96), or confronting
an empirical association for which “the nature of [the causal] mechanism
remains unclear” (p. 97), or up against empirical findings that “raise some
serious problems of interpretation,” and because “the evidence is fragile,”
“robust conclusions cannot be drawn” (p. 107), or confessing that “this kind of
calculation is fraught with uncertainty” (p. 170). To resolve conflicting
theoretical and empirical considerations, Pryor often simply judges on the
basis of his “subjective impression” (p. 359). At one point, he writes that
“the rate of technology advance is the key, and this is difficult to predict”
(p. 171). In fact, it is impossible to predict, as past prognosticators have
demonstrated repeatedly. What Pryor says in a particular context might well
have been said of the entire enterprise: “Given the nature of the data, the
results of the statistical experiments … should be considered only as
suggestive” (p. 188). What he observes about cultural trends might have been
observed equally about nearly everything discussed in the book: “the analysis
of current culture and values may tell us little about the future” (p. 199).
Looming over the hodge-podge of micro-level examinations Pryor makes, one great
problem threatens to demolish any value the analyses might have. The author
himself acknowledges this threat, but he forges ahead anyhow. The great
difficulty arises because “the impact on the U.S. economic system of a severe
financial crisis or an adverse production shock would be great. Like a major
war, however, such events cannot be easily predicted” (p. 81). (Translation:
cannot be predicted.) “If such a depression occurs, its impact would probably
outweigh most of the other factors discussed in this book.” Yet, “in order to
analyze systematically these other factors impinging on the future of U.S.
capitalism, I assume … that an extremely serious downturn will not occur. …
that the U.S. will really have such a lucky break” (p. 81). Has the system
avoided big shocks such as major wars and financial collapses in the past?
Certainly not for any extended period. We would be hoping against hope to
suppose that whereas in the past the system has always been troubled
episodically by big crises, in the future it will be free of them. Yet when
they occur, all bets are off. This fact of historical life is just one of
several reasons why no science of history is possible, and therefore why no
long-range predictions deserve to be taken seriously. Trends exist, to be sure,
but the long-term development of any socio-economic system consists more
decisively in a series of contingencies laid end to end, with the realization
of each major contingency setting in train a new path-dependent process.
At the end, Pryor pulls together his expectations about the nature of U.S.
capitalism in 2050 — a sort of semi-fascist distopia, or “a capitalism with an
inhuman face” (p. 367) — as follows:
Along the political dimension, the overall level of governmental intervention
will be roughly the same, but with a different composition: public expenditures
will be higher, regulation of industry will be lower, government intervention
into the economy will be less effective, and repression of the population will
be harsher. Along the economic dimension, markets will be less competitive. And
along the social dimension, solidarity will probably be less, and, despite
increased affluence, the quality of our lives will deteriorate and economic
life will be more pitiless.
These results, combined with the ever-larger size of enterprises, point toward
a greater oligarchical control of both the state and the economy. That is,
economic and political elites will continue to fuse, government intervention in
the economy will be less aimed at raising the general welfare of the population
than at ameliorating certain economic problems faced by particular segments of
the elite. The decreasing progressivity of the tax structure and rising income
inequalities will be telling indicators of these developments. These trends
will be reinforced by declining political participation and mounting distrust
toward the government, in major part because more people will feel powerless to
influence policies and events. Expenditures on internal security, pensions, and
health will increase, primarily to palliate political discontent that might
erupt into serious domestic strife (p. 364).
The good news is that one can place hardly any weight at all on these forlorn
forecasts.
Having plowed through Pryor’s big, dense book, the reader who has retained his
sympathy for the author may wish that the labor theory of value were valid. If
it were, then one could be sure that Pryor, who must have labored long and hard
over this project, had created a work of considerable value. Alas, the labor
theory of value is bunk; and, sad to say, the product of Pryor’s labors is not
likely to find a high place in anyone’s subjective value ranking.
Robert Higgs is senior fellow in political economy at the Independent
Institute, editor of The Independent Review, and author of many articles
and books, including Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth
of American Government (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987). His
current research includes further investigations in the political economy of
war.
Subject(s): | Economywide Country Studies and Comparative History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |