Author(s): | O'Hearn, Denis |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Gray, Jane , Jane |
Published by EH.NET (February 2003)
Denis O’Hearn, The Atlantic Economy: Britain, the US and Ireland.
Manchester and New York: Manchester University Press and Palgrave, 2001. xiii +
241 pp. ?45/$79.95 (hardcover), ISBN: 0-7190-5973-9.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Jane Gray, Department of Sociology, National University
of Ireland, Maynooth.
This book has two aims. First, it seeks to explain Irish economic development
within the theoretical framework of world-systems theory by locating Ireland in
the context of its history as an ‘intermediating zone’ within the Atlantic
economy dominated first by Britain and then by the United States. Second, the
book uses the Irish case to develop world-systems concepts and to transcend
some of the limitations of the paradigm. Denis O’Hearn (Reader in Sociology at
Queen’s University, Belfast) correctly points out that most definitions of
‘coreness’ and ‘perhipherality’ within the world-systems literature are
descriptive rather than analytical. For example coreness is often defined in
terms of the degree to which economic activities are capital-intensive, labor
is skilled and wages and profits high, in contrast to peripherality where the
opposite characteristics are true. The problem with these definitions is that
they cannot explain why historical core-periphery configurations are reproduced
over time, nor can they explain why some places change their position within
the hierarchy. O’Hearn argues that coreness should be defined in terms of the
ability to capture and localize innovative economic activities that have the
capacity to generate wider economic growth. Thus he argues that at key
‘switching points’ the hegemonic powers of the Atlantic economy prevented Irish
economic and political actors from industrializing in innovative economic
clusters, redirecting the Irish economy towards activities that served their
own strategic interests, and leaving Irish industrial firms and sectors to try
to compete on the basis of semi-peripheral ‘adaptive response’ — that is by
lowering wages and intensifying worker effort. In describing and explaining
this process O’Hearn seeks to transcend another shortcoming of world-systems
theory — its tendency towards teleological accounts of particular local and
regional economic histories that leave little room for contingency. He
understands the actions of Irish political and economic elites in terms of
‘iterative problem solving.’ Their attempts to industrialize were constrained
by the institutional consequences of Ireland’s initial incorporation to the
evolving world-economy, and by the paths taken at earlier ‘switch points,’ but
the outcomes of their efforts — and of those of core elites — were never
pre-determined.
O’Hearn identifies three cycles of industrialization in Ireland associated with
three cycles of change within the Atlantic economy. In the first cycle, Britain
sought to challenge Dutch supremacy within the world economy by shifting its
center from the Baltic to the Atlantic. During this period, British interests
led to the suppression of the (potentially innovative) Irish woollen industry,
and to the promotion of linen manufacturing which, according to O’Hearn, was
clearly semi-peripheral in character. In the second cycle, efforts to
industrialize on the basis of the innovative cotton manufacture were frustrated
by British trade policies that ultimately led Irish factory entrepreneurs to
revert to the linen industry. The third cycle was associated with the rise of
U.S. hegemony within the Atlantic economy after the Second World War. The newly
independent Irish state had experienced a phase of ‘easy industrialization’
under import-substitution policies between the wars, but switched to a policy
of export-led industrialization by the late1950s, partly in response to the
structural limitations of ISI, but also under pressure from the United States,
which had made Ireland a beneficiary of Marshall Aid, despite its stance of
neutrality during the war. In an influential article published in 1989, O’Hearn
argued that export-led industrialization had created slow economic growth in
Ireland because trans-national corporations repatriated profits, failed to
establish linkages to the local economy, and because the policy of ‘radical’
free trade led to the collapse of indigenous industry. He elaborates on these
arguments and provides more detailed evidence in Chapter 6 of this book. At the
end of the 1980s, when Ireland was experiencing economic stagnation, and high
levels of unemployment and emigration, the thesis that export-led
industrialization simply created new forms of ‘dependency’ seemed highly
plausible. But the boom that began in Ireland in the mid-1990s has made the
dependency argument less fashionable. Has the ‘Celtic Tiger’ undermined
O’Hearn’s case? In Chapter 7 he argues that the extraordinary levels of growth
achieved after 1994 can be explained by the sheer size of the flow of
U.S.-based trans-national corporation (TNC) investments. This in turn was due
to: the resurgence of the United States in the world-economy; the new strategy
of ‘flexible specialisation’ that encouraged TNCs to agglomerate their
off-shore investments in foreign-investment complexes; the skill of the Irish
Industrial Development Authority in attracting inward investment; and the
‘pro-business’ environment created by Ireland’s ‘social partnership’ model of
industrial relations together with its low corporate tax regime. He suggests
that once investment flows slow down, Ireland remains at risk of slow economic
growth due to the scale of foreign investment stocks. TNCs continue to
repatriate profits and, according to O’Hearn, the extent to which they have
established linkages to domestic firms has been overstated, as has the
potential of the indigenous software industry. He emphasizes the extent to
which the ‘Celtic Tiger’ has increased social inequality due to labor-market
segmentation and a relative decline in state spending. In the absence of
articulated economic growth based on a national system of innovation, the Irish
state must attempt to sustain economic growth through the continued adoption of
liberal policies that impede social development.
This book makes an important contribution to the understanding of Irish
socio-economic change by placing it in a comparative and theoretical
perspective. This is in contrast to much of the sociological scholarship on
Ireland, which continues to be ahistorical, showing little understanding or
appreciation of social change before the twentieth century. More importantly,
perhaps, it makes a significant contribution to world-systems theory — indeed
it has recently won the ‘Distinguished Scholarship’ book award from the
Political Economy of the World-System Section of the American Sociological
Association. O’Hearn has created a dynamic model of socio-economic change
within the modern world-system that links the emergence and development of
historical regularities to the contingent ‘problem-solving’ of elite actors at
particular historical moments. In my view the model would be enhanced by more
attention to non-elite agency. For example, in his account of the ‘first cycle
of industrial transformation’ (Chapter 3), O’Hearn describes the shift from
woollens to linen as “a shift away from an industry with the potential to
develop core production relations to one that clearly induced the expansion of
semi-peripheral domestic production” (pp. 67-68). This was because woollens
(and later cottons) tended to be organized under putting-out systems, whereas
the Irish linen industry was organized under the ‘Kaufsystem’ whereby “cottage
producers supplied their own raw materials, which they processed and wove into
textiles in an integrated production system, until they sold the cloth to
merchants in the marketplace” (p. 68). It is true that linen was more likely to
be organized under the Kaufsystem because the nature of the raw material meant
that small-holders were able to supply enough from their own resources to
absorb the labor capacity of their households. However that in itself did not
prevent the development of more complex ways of organizing production in other
European linen manufacturing regions. In my view, in order to understand why
the Kaufsystem persisted in Ireland, it is necessary to take account of the
household strategies of the producers themselves, strategies that were not
entirely determined by the actions of British or Irish elites. Of course taking
account of non-elite strategies is not inconsistent with O’Hearn’s analysis.
For example, household decisions might be traced, in part, to some of the
institutional consequences of incorporation described in Chapter 2.
Nonetheless, including non-elite strategies would add another dimension of
contingency and variance to this sophisticated account of the relationships
between particular, local events and long-term patterns of global economic
change.
Reference:
O’Hearn, Denis. 1989. “The Irish Case of Dependency: An Exception to the
Exceptions?” American Sociological Review, 54, 4: 578-596.
Jane Gray is Lecturer in Sociology at the National University of Ireland,
Maynooth. Her chapter on “The Irish, Scottish and Flemish Linen Industries
during the Long Eighteenth Century” is forthcoming in B. Collins and P.
Ollerenshaw, editors, The European Linen Industry in Historical
Perspective (Oxford) and she has recently completed a book manuscript on
the Irish linen industry.
Subject(s): | International and Domestic Trade and Relations |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |