Author(s): | Andersen, Birgitte |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Khan, B. Zorina |
Published by EH.NET (July 2001)
Birgitte Andersen, Technological Change and the Evolution of Corporate
Innovation: The Structure of Patenting, 1890-1990. Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar, 2001. viii + 285 pp. $90 (cloth), ISBN: 1-84064-121-5.
Reviewed for EH.NET by B. Zorina Khan, Department of Economics, Bowdoin
College.
The research in this book is dedicated to the proposition that technological
change is best treated from an “evolutionary system perspective.” This
perspective raises “the difficult questions about what is it which constitutes
a distinct unit of membership, and what the processes are which create the
changing structure of this membership, and which explain how systems emerge,
grow, decline and disappear.” It also “applies a capability perspective to the
dynamics of industries, in which the industry systems’ populations are derived
from the changing distribution of capabilities of firms within industries,
participating in the generation and exploitation of the common knowledge
bases. This latter competence bloc view on systemic change is taken from one
of the most comprehensive attempts to investigate the systemic aspects of
innovation and competition at the microeconomic level, and which is provided
by Eliasson (1997) and colleagues” (p. 13).
The analysis is based on a data set of patents filed in the United States
between 1890 and 1990. Most scholars who use these data issue the caveat that
patents provide an imperfect index of inventive activity (since many
inventions are not patented), and a quite poor measure of innovation (since
few patents result in the commercialization of the underlying invention). This
is especially true in the modern period, because firms have tended to
appropriate returns through other means than property rights in patents.
Birgitte Andersen (Senior Lecturer, Department of Management, Birbeck College,
University of London) instead contends that previous research supports the
view that the propensity for corporations to patent is between 66 percent and
87 percent, and that “40% to 60% of total patent applications actually
progress to innovations” (p.20). Given these assumptions, the author proceeds
to analyze stocks of patents in order to draw conclusions about the nature of
technological innovation during the past century. Moreover, it is “argued that
patent data can serve as a proxy for accumulated technological impact or
socio-economic importance” (p. 25).
The data are organized in terms of technology classes. Based on this measure,
technology appears to progress in terms of small incremental improvements
instead of large fluctuations or discontinuous waves of creative destruction.
Technological change seems to have become more complementary and interrelated
over time. Contagion models are commonly used to examine the diffusion of new
products and technologies, and other studies have found that the pattern of
commercialization follows an S-shape. The book devotes one chapter to fitting
logistic curves to the accumulated patent stocks, and presents forty-four
graphs of the results for the various categories as well as twenty pages of
tabulated information on the properties of the associated cycles, which
confirm the logistic fit.
Time series analysts tend to speculate about the existence of long cycles or
waves in innovations by grouping key or basic applications of technology.
Andersen focuses on takeoffs in patents accumulated over time. She identifies
a wave between 1926-1934 associated with chemical technologies, and electrical
and mechanical inventions; a second wave between 1957-78 for chemical,
electrical, mechanical and transportation patents; and a third currently
underway in pharmaceuticals and biotechnology, electrical devices, and
mechanical technologies. For instance, the interwar chemical industry was
propelled by patented discoveries relating to distillation, coal and petroleum
products, and bleaching and dying; whereas the postwar period was noted for
chemical patents in synthetic resins and fibers, photographic chemistry, and
agricultural chemicals. (On the other hand, she finds no takeoffs in the
patent records for the periods between 1934-1947 and 1977-1985.) These
takeoffs tend to be introduced in the industrial area that is closest to the
particular technology, although over time this pattern appears to have become
attenuated because patents have become more interrelated.
At the firm level, the book categorizes some 284 large corporations in
existence between 1930 through 1990 in terms of their status as technological
followers or leaders and their degree of specialization in the fastest growing
fields of patenting. The author tracks changes in status over time, and argues
that firms do not readily develop capabilities in new areas. When there are
radical changes in technology former leaders lose standing although their
advantage is not completely eroded. The following chapter explores a data set
that includes “corporate technological top-leaders and largest contributors,”
such as Philips, Corning, Dow, and Chrysler. The patterns suggest that the
degree of concentration in technological leadership has fallen over time, and
declined most rapidly during periods when the growth in patent stock was
highest. Since only a few specific examples are sketchily discussed to
illustrate the process, the mechanisms that account for the prevalence of
statis, path dependence or change within corporations remain unclear.
In the final chapter the author’s overall conclusions are outlined in special
boxes and labeled as “Stylised Facts” I through XXI. These include insights
such as “some trajectories are more likely to be followed than others”
(Stylised Fact II), and “the innovative and competitive landscape underpinning
the dynamics of firms within industries is constantly changing” (Stylised Fact
XIII). Some of these Facts look very similar to each other (X and XXI, for
instance.) They are further clarified by explanations in the following vein:
“although technology develops over a broad complex technological front, some
technologies within the broad system are in the forefront or at takeoff at
certain times, and other technologies at other times” (p. 251).
The price of this book is $90, so it is difficult to understand why the
publisher appears to have economized by not employing an editor. This is the
only way one can reasonably explain the numerous grammatical and spelling
errors, logical non sequiturs, inaccuracies, misquotes, opaque prose, and
prolific use of jargon that clutter almost every page. According to the book
jacket, the potential audience for this book includes economists, historians
of technology, students, business analysts and policy makers. In reality the
market is most likely limited to libraries with porous budget constraints.
B. Zorina Khan is Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Bowdoin
College. She has most recently published “‘Not for Ornament’: Patenting
Activity by Women Inventors,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History,
Fall 2000; and (co-authored with Kenneth L. Sokoloff) “The Early Development
of Intellectual Property Institutions in the United States,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Fall 2001. She is the author of a book on the
economic history of patents and copyrights (forthcoming, Cambridge University
Press).
Subject(s): | History of Technology, including Technological Change |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |