Author(s): | Alston, Lee J. Ferrie, Joseph P. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Heinicke, Craig |
Published by EH.NET (December 2000)
Lee J. Alston and Joseph P. Ferrie, Southern Paternalism and the American
Welfare State: Economics, Politics, and Institutions in the South
1865-1965. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998. xii + 170 pp.
$49.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-521-62210-7.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Craig Heinicke, Department of Economics,
Baldwin-Wallace College, Berea, Ohio.
Why was political power in the American South summoned in defense of a
“…complex system of reciprocal duties and obligations that had bound
agricultural employers and their workers, the elaborate but often unspoken
protocol of paternalism…” (p. 1)? What led that system to disappear, and why
was the defense of paternalism abandoned almost overnight, after having
persisted for close to a century following the U.S. Civil War? In this
important book, Lee Alston and Joseph Ferrie not only address the complexity
of southern paternalism, but also carry forward the task suggested by their
title — explaining how southern political interests affected the timing and
expansion of the “welfare state” legislative program in the U.S.
The authors argue that paternalism, also familiar as the “patron-client”
relationship, reduced transactions costs in labor-intensive southern
agriculture. Paternalism is said to be characterized by an implicit contract
wherein landowners provided a multitude of benefits to workers. Workers
responded by supplying “good and faithful labor,” including a long-term
commitment to the landowner. Cheaper to landlords than the available
alternatives, paternalism thus helped to sustain the agricultural economy of
the South for nearly a century after the disappearance of slavery in the U.S.
By contrast, “welfare state” programs would have substituted for the
landlord-as-benefactor and eroded such traditional relations.
The book’s first two chapters examine the inner workings of paternalism, as
well as its subtle contradictions in this setting. Among other matters the
authors consider the provision of medical care, protection from racial
violence directed at African-Americans, and agreements to “stand good” for
certain tenants in the face of creditors, as devices to ensure self-monitoring
by workers. That southern elites took great pains to preserve the system is
demonstrated by the political power invoked to defeat or co-opt welfare state
legislation such as the Social Security Act (chapter three) or the Farm
Security Administration (chapter four) that would weaken the social ties of
the traditional system. On the other hand, politicians supported the federal
Bracero program that had few direct benefits to southern elites but which
served to deter outmigration to western cotton regions (chapter five).
The sudden disappearance of this system is examined in chapter six. Here
Alston and Ferrie argue that “plowing up” paternalism resulted when machines
invaded agriculture and reduced the costs of monitoring and turnover and thus
the need for paternalism from the landowner’s perspective. The unemployment
associated with declining demand for labor also replaced the “efficiency wage”
feature of paternalism with one more akin to that of an industrial setting. At
this stage of political history, southern senators and congressmen still held
key positions in committees where the legislative agenda was set. Despite
their continued political power, they began to withdraw their opposition to
welfare state legislation, as the economic imperative of paternalism declined.
Once cotton agriculture was mechanized, southern politicians began to favor
the types of programs they had earlier resisted, programs that accentuated
outmigration. Workers who had benefited from paternalism despite their
distaste for many aspects of the system (deference by blacks to white
landlords, for instance), also no longer found a reason to buy into the
system.
To make its arguments, the book uses mainly documentary and “circumstantial”
evidence, and, less often, quantitative data. Alternative explanations are
considered throughout. Racism and ideology, for example, may explain some part
of the absence of federal welfare expenditures funneled through southern
states in the 1930s. Still, the effort to exclude agricultural workers from
the Old-Age Insurance and Unemployment Insurance portions of the Social
Security Act, for instance, requires more than racism to explain it.
Alternative explanations also make it difficult to understand the expansion of
federal welfare programs in the 1950s and 1960s and the absence of southern
resistance to that expansion (pp. 58-59). The authors show the inadequacy of
such alternative explanations, and consistently demonstrate the explanatory
power of institutions and paternalism.
Among the unresolved questions raised by the book, is the degree to which
paternalism was a self-conscious attempt to elicit work effort and long-term
commitment, and the extent to which it was mainly the result of custom, its
manifestation seen by landlords as their “duty.” At one point Alston and
Ferrie argue that the more landlords appeared as beneficent, the more likely
they were to receive loyalty and hard work in return (p. 24). Yet one wonders
how effectively landlords could manipulate the system. Perhaps it does not
matter. Even if workers did not view landowners as charitable, they may have
responded to seemingly well-intentioned acts with increased work effort,
sensing that doing otherwise meant risking valuable necessities that could not
be purchased readily in the market. On the other hand, the legitimacy of the
system was at stake and any sense that magnanimity was false could undermine,
even if it would not destroy, the foundations of the social system. This
tension remains unresolved in the book. Since motives are not observed but
outcomes are, this is perhaps the best that can be achieved.
An unresolved question of a quite different nature involves the effect of
mechanization on monitoring costs. How great were the reductions in monitoring
and turnover costs wrought by the tractor and the mechanical cotton picker? If
the cost reductions were large enough that they led to the disappearance of
paternalism, why was great energy not devoted to reducing these costs? Perhaps
it was. After all, after World War II both public and private agents devoted
substantial resources to reducing the labor content in cotton cultivation and
to mechanizing the harvest in the South. Alston and Ferrie’s work suggests the
question of how large transactions costs were relative to the cost of the pure
labor input. The assumption of exogenous technology means this issue never
receives full attention. Some assessment of the matter and measurement of the
transactions costs savings — admittedly a difficult undertaking — might
bolster their paternalism hypothesis. Yet despite these unresolved questions,
the authors’ clear presentation and careful consideration of the evidence
produce a convincing argument in the end.
The range of the historical evidence used by Alston and Ferrie, and the
inevitable paradoxes that emerge, suggest that interpretations of such
evidence will vary. My guess is that economists will be more sympathetic to
the authors’ interpretation than others, but traditional historians will also
find much of merit here, as well as, perhaps, some points of contention. My
own view is that if disagreements emerge, this wouldconstitute a strength
rather than a weakness of the book: we need a fuller debate over these issues,
particularly given the relative silence among economic historians on the
abrupt disappearance of the plantation system compared with the attention
focused on earlier periods in southern history. Alston and Ferrie’s book not
only directs our attention to this relatively neglected period, but also
applies what has become the “new institutional economics” to questions well
suited to that framework. The compelling clarity of their central argument
means that we will learn all the more from dissertation topics and other
research projects that will most certainly follow their lead.
The main argument of the book is skillfully presented and convincing. The
approach, which reaches beyond economics and history and into the disciplines
of political science and sociology, remains fresh and innovative, despite the
book’s “long gestation” (p. xi) period. The book performs several valuable
services for the economic historian. First of all, it informs us on an
important case study in which informal but powerful institutions are
interwoven with those of formal political power. While acknowledging
ambiguities, the authors are able to sustain their main line of argument. The
authors also move us decisively forward on the matter of “?the demise of
plantation paternalism, a socioeconomic system that had endured the better
part of a century” (p. 98). We know that labor-intensive agriculture vanished
in the South, but we have here an explanation for why the entire set of
informal institutions vanished with it, and vanished so extraordinarily
quickly. Finally, as contemporary electorates and leaders sift through and
debate the merits of the welfare state and its role in “mixed” economic
systems, we benefit from the insights of Alston and Ferrie. We are shown a
case where political power imbalances and a set of legislative rules combined
at one time to thwart, and then later to promote a wide ranging legislative
program — a program whose effects have been widespread and long lasting, but
the permanence of which is anything but assured.
Craig Heinicke, Associate Professor of Economics at Baldwin-Wallace College,
is engaged in on-going research on the mechanization of cotton agriculture in
the U.S. South, labor markets and African-American migration during and after
World War II. For a recent example, see “Southern Tenancy, Machines and
Production Scale on the Eve of the Cotton Picker’s Arrival,” (1999), Social
Science History, 23, 3 (Fall).
Subject(s): | Social and Cultural History, including Race, Ethnicity and Gender |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |