Author(s): | Barringer, Mark Daniel |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Hill, Peter J. |
Published by EH.NET (August 2002)
Mark Daniel Barringer, Selling Yellowstone: Capitalism and the Construction
of Nature. Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas, 2002. viii +250 pp.
$29.95 (hardback), ISBN: 0-7006-1167-3.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Peter J. Hill, Department of Business and Economics,
Wheaton College, Wheaton, Illinois.
On March 1, 1872, President Ulysses S. Grant signed the Yellowstone Park Act,
setting aside over two million acres “as a pleasuring ground for the benefit
and the enjoyment of the people” with the additional provision that there was
to be protection against “wanton destruction of the fish and game found within
said Park.” Further guidance for the operation of Yellowstone came with the
creation of the National Park Service in 1916, which specified that it was duty
of the new agency “to conserve the scenery and the natural and historic objects
and wildlife therein, and to provide for the enjoyment of the same in such a
manner and by such means as will leave them unimpaired for future generations.”
Needless to say, there is much room for interpretation in phrases such as “the
benefit and the enjoyment of the people” and “unimpaired for future
generations.” Does this mean that any and all visitors should be welcomed to
the park? What if such visitations resulted in ecological damage? And how
should the visitors to be cared for? What sort of services should be provided
for them? Should the provision be carried out by government or by private
entities? In the case of Yellowstone National Park, the lodging, meals, and
transportation services have been provided for by private enterprise, and Mark
Barringer has provided a useful history of this commercial activity.
From the very beginning, it was clear that Congress did not plan to maintain
and operate the commercial facilities that would be necessary for tourists to
enjoy the features of the park. However, Congress was also unclear as to the
nature of the contract between the federal government as owner and private
individuals as providers of transportation, housing, and meals. There were
ongoing incentive problems in that a private entity needed an assurance of a
long-term contract in order to make any substantial investment in facilities.
But such a contract meant the concessionaire would face little competition and
could charge monopoly prices. The result was that the private operations in the
park became a regulated monopoly, with all of the incentive and information
problems inherent in such an arrangement. To complicate matters, the
perceptions of the role of the park in the American psyche have changed
dramatically and, particularly in more recent decades, have resulted in
conflict over how the park should be used and preserved.
From the creation of the park in 1872 until the completion of the Northern
Pacific (NP) Railway close to its northern boundary in 1883, small-scale
commercial interests provided accommodation and transportation services within
the park. The original enabling act required leases to conduct commerce but
none of these early entrepreneurs possessed such leases, nor did the
superintendent have sufficient budget to enforce the lease provision.
The NP Railway quickly understood that if it was to profit from hauling
passengers to Yellowstone, appropriate facilities would need to be provided.
Therefore several individuals, all major investors in the NP, formed the
Yellowstone National Park Improvement Company (YNPIC) and applied for an
exclusive lease to provide hotel services and stage coach tours of the park.
Although people could still enter the park in their own wagons, the YNPIC
controlled most of the services within the bounds of the park and cooperated
with the Northern Pacific Railway in bringing tourists to the area. Barringer
recognizes the problem of monopoly control by private interests over the
provision of services, but there is another side to the coin that he does not
acknowledge. With very low access fees, the park suffered from a congestion
externality, but the fact that the Northern Pacific Railway had an almost
complete monopoly on transportation to the park and the YNPIC controlled most
of the transportation and lodging within the park meant that they had strong
incentives to internalize that externality. Therefore, from 1883 until 1915,
when automobiles were allowed into Yellowstone, the park probably experienced
its best management. There was a strong incentive by the railroad to operate
the park in a business-like manner and to provide the optimal experience for
visitors.
The YNPIC evolved into another entity, the Yellowstone Park Association, in
1886, again with Northern Pacific financial backing. Throughout this period
most of the visitors entered Yellowstone by way of Mammoth Hot Springs, after
having purchased an excursion fare on the railroad that included a
five-and-a-half-day tour of the park, staying in YPA facilities and traveling
in company stage coaches.
In 1915, the park opened its borders to automobiles, which changed the nature
of the business for concessionaires, and in 1916 the National Park Service was
created. This new government agency had the explicit responsibility of granting
the rights to provide commercial services and also to regulate the nature and
quality of those services. The first director of the National Park Service,
Stephen Mather, believed that competition among concessionaires was harmful to
the traveling public and that monopolies for each part of the operation would
make the administrative tasks simpler and also better satisfy visitors. He
chose a company with close ties to the Northern Pacific to be the primary
operator of concessions. Although private individuals could enter in their own
automobiles, the railroad was still the primary means of cross-country
transportation and the touring buses provided by the Yellowstone Park
Transportation Company were a popular way of seeing the park.
Throughout the 1920s, the commercial interests in the park formed an active
alliance with the National Park Service to provide a sanitized experience of
the natural wonders of the region. The National Park Service killed predators
in order to protect antelope, deer and elk. In the Lamar Valley a buffalo ranch
was established where bison were bred and fed for the viewing enjoyment of the
public.
The 1930s, however, saw the beginning of a struggle over the appropriate use of
the park. Until this point, the National Park Service (NPS) and the
concessionaires had operated with the same overall objective, to provide
services for a large number of visitors and to give them a safe and somewhat
artificial “wilderness experience.” The Wilderness Society was founded in 1935
and it provided a rallying point for those who believed that human intrusion in
the park needed to be reduced.
The conflict between those who wanted development and expansion of facilities
and those who preferred to limit any human encroachment upon nature intensified
throughout the 1940s and 1950s. In 1955, the National Park Service created
Mission 66, a long-term project scheduled for completion in 1966, the fiftieth
anniversary of the NPS. Mission 66 involved massive development of concessions
facilities in almost all of the national parks with a major focus on
Yellowstone. The plan involved large-scale expansion of facilities within the
park by private developers and accompanying improvements in roads and other
facilities by the government. Mission 66 turned into a major battleground
between those who wished to preserve the park in its “natural” state and those
who wished to develop it. The traditional alliance between the National Park
Service and the concessionaires fell apart in the 1960s and since then there
have been continued revisions of contracts between private entities and the
government, and continued debates about the role that Yellowstone National Park
is to play in the national experience.
Selling Yellowstone provides numerous insights into the awkward
structure of the contract between the public and the private sector in
Yellowstone National Park. Both the private operators of facilities and the
National Park Service faced an incentive structure that made it difficult to
have efficient management and an accurate representation of consumer and voter
preferences. And, since the right to operate in the park was valuable,
rent-seeking occurred to obtain that privilege.
The most significant problem with the book is that the author’s rhetoric
sometimes gets carried away and he claims more than his evidence can support.
For instance, he concludes the book by suggesting that “despite popular
perceptions that the park was protected from commercial exploitation, the NPS
and its concessioner partners virtually owned Yellowstone, selling it piecemeal
to receptive customers as if it were an inexhaustible, self-replenishing
commodity” (p. 173-74). Barringer seems to think it necessary to make rather
sweeping claims of exploitation and of “selling off the park.” However, his
analysis leads to the more modest conclusion that competing interest groups,
both inside and outside of government, tried to gain control to further their
own interests. Neither the government nor the private sector operated in a very
workable institutional structure and it is not surprising that the results were
somewhat disappointing. Nevertheless, as a narrative history of the attempts to
provide services to visitors through a combination of public and private
efforts, the book is a successful enterprise.
Peter J. Hill is professor of economics at Wheaton College and a Senior
Associate at PERC, Bozeman, Montana. He is the author of numerous articles on
property rights in the American West. He is presently working on a book-length
manuscript with Terry L. Anderson entitled The Not So Wild, Wild West:
Property Rights on the Frontier.
Subject(s): | Urban and Regional History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |