Author(s): | Sanders, Elizabeth |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Friedman, Gerald |
Published by EH.NET (April 2000)
Elizabeth Sanders, Roots of Reform: Farmers, Workers, and the American
State, 1877-1917. Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1999. x + 532 pp.
$16.00 (paper), ISBN: 0-226-73477-3; $48.00 (cloth), 0-226-73476-5.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Gerald Friedman, Department of Economics, University of
Massachusetts,
Since the publication in 1963 of Gabriel Kolko’s The Triumph of
Conservatism, scholars have been highly suspicious of American
progressivism. Working from a ‘corporate liberalism’ perspective, Kolko,
James Weinstein, Martin Sklar, James Livingston, and others have interpreted
Progressive Era reforms, such as railroad regulation,
anti-trust, the Federal Reserve system, and workers’ compensation, as products
of nefarious capitalist campaigns. In this story, the new, giant corporations
used ‘reform’ programs to control markets, reduce competition,
and replace worker militancy with complacency. This puts studies of the early
American welfare state in sharp contrast with comparable studies for Canada
and Europe. There, a social democratic coalition linking militant labor with
agrarian radicals is credited with pushing state programs regulating labor and
product markets over the objections of capitalists.
Such grass-roots radical
groups disappear from corporate liberal studies of the American Progressive
Era, replaced by ingenious and scheming corporate capitalists. Early
welfare-state programs in Canada and Europe, are signs of the growth in power
of a nascent working class. In
the United States, by contrast, they are viewed as signs of the emergence of a
modern ruling capitalist class.
It may be that the welfare state began to look more attractive to American
scholars after it began to be dismantled. Or perhaps its undoing in
an era of weak unions and triumphant corporate capitalism encouraged scholars
to reexamine labor and capital’s role in the creation of the welfare state.
Discounting the impact of corporate capitalists, Theda Skocpol, for example,
uses state-centered and
maternalist models to attribute early welfare-state initiatives in the United
States to a coalition uniting women’s groups with professional reformers.
Others have applied society-centered and social-democratic models to the United
States,
including political scientist Richard Valelly, and labor historians Julie
Greene and Richard Schneirov. They have shown the extent of political action by
Progressive Era labor and radical farmers, and the impact of their militancy on
both the national and local politics
.
Enter Elizabeth Sanders. Rejecting corporate liberalism, she argues that
Progressive-era reforms were championed by a reform coalition uniting organized
labor, middle-class reformers, and radical farmers. More, Sanders rejects both
the state-centered approach associated with Skocpol and labor historians’
social-democratic approach to argue that the real driving force behind the
early welfare state in the United States came from the country side, from
politically mobilized farmers in the South and West.
Dismissing progressive intellectuals as too isolated and organized labor as
too weak and disorganized, Sanders argues “that agrarian movements constituted
the most important political force driving the development of the American
national state in the first half century before World War I. And by shaping
the form of early regulatory legislation and establishing the centrality of the
farmer-labor alliance to progressive reform and the Democratic Party,
the agrarian influence was felt for years thereafter”
(p. 1).
Sanders supports this strong statement by examining roll-call votes in Congress
on several major Progressive-Era laws. Using county-level data on manufacturing
value added per capita in 1919, she divides the United States into three
regional blocks. These include a “core” of highly industrialized localities,
mostly in the Northeast, a “periphery” in the South and West,
and “diverse” localities mostly in the Midwest and along the border of the
other two. Examining votes on such measures as extending ICC jurisdiction,
the Clayton Act, the Underwood Tariff, the income tax, the Federal Reserve Act,
and vocational training, she shows how congressmen from the periphery,
favored an ‘agrarian statist agenda’ of state regulation and intervention meant
to
redistribute wealth and power towards farmers, wage laborers, and residents of
the periphery. Their agenda was enacted when senators and representatives from
the periphery joined with allies from diverse localities, generally progressive
Republican insurgents, and a few core Democrats closely allied with labor
unions. By contrast, this reform agenda was vigorously opposed by core
Republicans associated with major corporations and industrial and financial
capital. In this way, Sanders argues, the alliance
of farmers and organized labor in the American Progressive Era resembled the
farmer-labor alliances behind social democratic reforms and the early welfare
state in Scandinavia and elsewhere described in the works of Gosta
Esping-Andersen, Leo Loubere and
Seymour Martin Lipset.
Sanders’s work is a major contribution to our understanding of politics in the
Progressive Era. By restoring ‘farmer’ to the ‘farmer-labor’ coalition,
she moves scholarship back to an earlier appreciation of the role of agrarians
in American radicalism, providing background, for example, to the role agrarian
radicals like Iowa’s Henry Wallace and Minnesota’s Floyd Olson played in
building the New Deal coalition of the 1930s. Showing how,
even before the New Deal, Democrats united
northern labor with peripheral agrarians to advance economic reforms, she
broadens our understanding of the role of the Democratic Party in American
politics. United by more than racism, the Democrats were a party of reform
committed to advancing an agrarian statist agenda.
Thus Sanders provides new insight into the regional and industrial sources of
political parties’ economic programs. But the parties themselves are a weak
link in her argument. Slavery, the Civil War, and segregation made regions
almost synonymous with political party in the United States. In the
Progressive Era, almost all southern congressmen were Democrats, but
Republicans controlled most congressional seats from the Northeast.
Sanders’s regional division between ‘core’ and ‘periphery,’ therefore,
confounds party and region, separating ‘core’ Republicans and ‘peripheral’
Democrats. Sanders supports her argument with two-way tables showing support
for various progressive reforms by representatives or senators by region. But
she rarely distinguishes between voting by party in each region and never
performs the statistical tests needed to determine the relative importance of
party and region in congressional voting. But it is clear in her tables that
there is a strong partisan component to congressional voting. In the final
vote on the Payne-Aldrich Tariff of 1909, for example,
80% of representatives from the core supported passage compared with only 33%
of those from the periphery (p. 225). However, the vote was even more partisan
than it was regional: 98% of Democrats opposed the tariff bill against 99% of
Republicans. Did peripheral representatives oppose the bill because they were
from the periphery or because they were Democrats? The same question can be
asked for other partisan measures. The Federal Reserve Act, for example, was
supported by 100% of Senate Democrats against 90% of Republicans (p. 252). A
measure in 1910 forbidding the use of Justice Department funds to prosecute
unions under the antitrust laws was supported by 98
% of House Democrats but was opposed by 74% of Republicans (p. 343).
Sanders chooses to emphasize the strong regional alignment in all of these
votes; she may as well have seen them as partisan votes driven by the
imperatives of political coalition building in an era of strong parties.
In addition, there may also be problems in Sanders’s regional classification by
manufacturing output per capita in 1919. Are all manufacturing regions the
same? Is it appropriate to place declining New England textile counties in the
same category as Pennsylvania steel towns and Washington State canning
communities? And is it appropriate to put Southern cotton regions dominated by
racism and sharecropping in the same peripheral category as western mining
communities, Minnesota dairy towns,
and wheat farmers on the Great Plains? Sanders could do a finer breakdown and
then provide statistical tests for using a higher level of aggregation.
This would be a great deal of work; but that may explain why God made graduate
students
.
Elizabeth Sanders is well aware of the partisanship and regional subtleties
behind the progressive era legislation she discusses. Beyond the statistical
analysis, she shows a firm understanding of the qualitative literature, the
congressional debates and the maneuvering among the leadership of Congress and
the Executive Branch. Roots of Reform is a work of the highest
scholarship, providing an insightful account of the origins of the American
welfare state. Whether one agrees or disagrees with her findings, Sanders’s
work marks a new beginning in the study of twentieth-century American politics.
Gerald Friedman is an Associate Professor of Economics at the University of
Massachusetts at Amherst. He is the author of State-Making and Labor
Movements
: France and the United States, 1876-1914 (Cornell University Press, 1999)
as well as numerous articles on the history of organized labor in the United
States and Europe.
Subject(s): | Markets and Institutions |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: Pre WWII |