Author(s): | Muir, Diana |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Knodell, Jane |
Published by EH.NET (May 2001)
Diana Muir, Reflections in Bullough’s Pond: Economy and Ecosystem in New
England. Hanover, NH: University Press of New England, 2000. x + 312 pp.
$26 (cloth); ISBN 0-87451-909-8.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Jane Knodell, Department of Economics, University of
Vermont.
This is a history of the material lives of the peoples who have lived in the
area we know today as New England, starting with the original
hunter-gatherers, dwelling on the farmers and mechanics of the nineteenth
century, and ending with affluent suburban commuter-consumers. The author,
herself a New Englander of the latter variety who lives on Bullough’s Pond in
Newton, Massachusetts, is interested in the way in which the material
conditions of life have, time and time again over the span of tens of
thousands of years, eventually encountered ecological constraints, and in the
way New Englanders have repeatedly responded. The story is punctuated by two
“revolutions,” the Neolithic and the Industrial, which were the responses to
two different ecological-economic crises, and ends with the author’s
contemplation on the need for a comparable third revolution today.
The book’s scope is fairly vast. Its contribution is to weave disparate social
and natural scientific literatures together into a well-written, interesting
narrative. This is history made palpable and personal, written by one who has
hiked New England’s mountains and wandered along its beaches. It is written to
enlighten a general audience, not to engage in scholarly debate (although Muir
draws on a number of literatures within economic history and does not hesitate
to stake a claim here and there). Muir starts at the beginning. Drawing on
archeology, anthropology, and ethnohistory, she explains how, after early
hunter-gatherers depleted the population of large game animals, they
eventually turned to agriculture (the “Neolithic Revolution”) combined with
fishing and small game hunting in managed forests. This way of provisioning
depended on an ample supply of forested land near the coast, a supply which
was being depleted as the first Europeans arrived in southern New England. But
before the “crisis of coastal deforestation” could be joined, the native New
Englanders faced a crisis of “extermination” through exposure to Old World
diseases to which they had no immunity (pp. 21-22). This, of course,
facilitated the settlement and expansion of the European population.
We hear very little about the fate of the original New Englanders from this
point on, as the author turns to the colonial economy created with the
migration of the Puritans and the westward expansion of the European
economies. From the very beginning, immigration, and then export markets
provided the external demand needed to propel a largely agricultural economy
forward. By the late eighteenth or early nineteenth century, given the
British-imposed limit on westward settlement, this economy had occupied all
the decent farmland. The response? Manufacturing, followed by
industrialization — the second revolution. For Muir, the threat of a decline
in economic status was a powerful incentive to entrepreneurship. Although the
region “faced the prospect of economic decline, . . . standards of nutruition,
health, and education were high enough to enable men to search for new ways
to earn a living” (p. 107).
Shoes were the most successful of many preindustrial solutions. The book
details the advance of protoindustrialization and the peddling system of
distribution in the early nineteenth century, by which time the region was no
longer feeding itself. Muir suggests, though, that economic decline would only
be forestalled once Yankees began to invent “machines that made machines.”
Muir does a masterful job of reviewing the important inventions and process
innovations that culminated in mechanized production across the array of
consumer and capital goods produced in New England. Government munitions
contracts helped to fund the development of new metal-working tools and
processes, which were then adopted in other sectors. Along the way, the motive
shifted from preserving a middle-class way of life to earning greater profits
from standardization, lower costs, lower prices, and greater sales. This was
now an economy organized around the principle of expansion which faced
barriers to expansion located within itself (in this case the size of the
internal market), not in nature. And it was an economy that would subsequently
fail to avert economic decline in the early twentieth century, but this
receives relatively little attention here other than to credit federal defense
spending for the postwar Massachusetts Miracle.
The ecological angle comes back in as Muir details the environmental
degradation brought about by industrialization and urbanization. We learn
about the ecological impacts of agriculture, husbandry, charcoal production,
mills and dams, commercial logging, city sewers, and commercial fishing.
Although the earlier material ways of life also changed their natural
environments, modern industry and modern life have degraded the rivers,
forests, and atmosphere in ways that now, Muir argues, threaten to undermine
our well-being. Muir hopes that the pressure of population on limited
resources is pushing us into a Third Revolution, in which we will develop and
adopt alternatives to fossil energy. But it is far from clear that either the
profit incentive, assisted by government fiscal policy, as in the Second
Revolution, or declining living standards among those in a position to address
the problem, as in the First Revolution, will move us in this direction.
Jane Knodell conducts research on the evolution and performance of antebellum
monetary institutions, with an emphasis on interregional payments and finance.
She recently published “The Demise of Central Banking and the Domestic
Exchanges: Evidence from Antebellum Ohio”, Journal of Economic History,
September 1998. At the University of Vermont, she teaches a course on the
economic history of early New England.
Subject(s): | Historical Geography |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | General or Comparative |