Published by EH.NET (March 2000)
John McDonald, Production Efficiency in Domesday England, 1086. London
and New York: Routledge, 1998, xiv + 240 pp. $85 (cloth), ISBN:
0-415-16187-8.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Maristella Botticini, Department of Economics,
Boston University.
On the cover page of John McDonald’s Production Efficiency in Domesday
England, 1086 it might be appropriate to include a warning label: “Reading
this book may have fatal consequences for certain scholars.” The reason is
simple: it takes a lot of energy and passion for a medievalist to keep reading
the book after page
14 when the author starts employing high-tech economic models (chapters 2 and
3) and fancy regressions (chapters 4). On the other hand, patient medievalists
(and other scholars as well) will be rewarded by learning that scholars have
been basically wrong
in arguing that English estates were run inefficiently by Norman conquerors.
According to McDonald (Professor of Economics at Flinders University of South
Australia) these estates were run at similar efficiency levels to comparable
production units in more modern economies, such as farms in the postbellum
U.S. South, farms in contemporary California, and surface coalmines in the U.S
(p. 137).
After a clear and insightful introductory chapter that describes the main
features of the English economy at the
time of the Norman conquest,
elucidates the data of the Domesday Book, and outlines the main themes of the
book, the reader enters with chapters 2 and 3 into a “jungle” of technical
models that explain the techniques used by the author to measure production
efficiency in agriculture. The core of the book is in chapters 4 and 6 where
McDonald applies these techniques to a sample of estates surveyed in the
Domesday Book (those of Essex lay estates).
The book addresses important questions such as: Which ten ants-in-chief ran
efficient estates? How was productivity affected by soil type, the size of the
estate, the tenancy agreement, the institutional framework of the time and the
proximity of a market center? Which inputs made the major contribution to the
net value of output? Did slaves make a greater contribution to the manorial
lord’s net income than peasants? What was the effect of feudal and manorial
systems, which discouraged mobility of inputs, on the system of production,
input productivities and total output produced? Given technology and the
institutional framework, were estates run efficiently?
Multivariate regression analysis carried out in chapter 4 indicates that
efficiency depended on the spatial location of the farm (in which hundred the
farm was located), but was not affected by the type of soil and proximity to
urban economies. Larger farms tended to be more efficient suggesting that
economies of scale were at work. Efficiency was influenced by whether an estate
was held in demesne by the
tenant-in-chief (estates being held in demesne tended to be more efficient) and
who the tenant-in-chief was. Estates with relatively more grazing were more
efficient than estates with relatively more arable or mixed farming. The
existence of some ancillary resources on the farm (beehives, mills, or
saltpans) seems to have made estates less efficient, whereas fisheries and
vineyards do not seem to have had any effect. Overall, English estates were run
efficiently by Norman conquerors. Yet the restrictions
and rigidities imposed by feudal and manorial systems had a negative impact on
agricultural efficiency (pp. 140-143).
While I highly recommend this book to both economists and historians, I think
it is worthwhile to stress some weaknesses. The first issue is why the author
does not compare medieval English agriculture to English agriculture in later
centuries. This would have been even more interesting than comparing Domesday
England to contemporary California farms or U. S.
surface coalmines. We could learn, for example, how the demise of the feudal
and manorial systems of production affected agricultural production in England,
or how the development of more important and significant urban centers
(compared to Maldon and Colchester in 1086) influenced agricultural
efficiency. Second, given that it is not always clear whether the annual value
of an estate included ancillary resources, one wonders if this can make the
comparisons of the efficiency of various estates meaningless. The author
dismisses the argument by arguing that the existence of ancillary resources
would have had opposite effects and that therefore their overall impact on
efficiency was probably minimal. But what about other incomes from feudal
rights that could have entered into the annual values of estates?
Another critical point is the organization of the book. The technical chapters
2 and 3 should have gone into large appendices. Those who know the frontier
technique are bored by reading these chapters; those who do not have the
knowledge to understand these chapters can be really discouraged from reading
the
book. A further minor criticism is of technical nature and has to do with the
multivariate regressions. The question is why the author does not include fixed
or random effects to
account for variables that do not vary across a tenant-in-chief or whoever was
running the farm. His abilities, experience, and other unobservable variables
could have affected the way he ran his estates.
The book requires a lot of patience and passion
for high-tech economy history. If one is willing to persevere and arrive at the
end of the book,
the effort is rewarded. Someone else can apply the same frontier technique to
Norfolk and Suffolk, for which, together with Essex, the Domesday Book provides
the most detailed information, and check whether McDonald’s findings still hold
for these counties. More importantly, someone can do the same exercise on
English agriculture for later periods and tell us whether and how the demise of
the feudal system affected agricultural efficiency.
Maristella Botticini’s research focuses on marriage markets, dowries,
intergenerational transfers, credit markets and Jewish lenders, and agrarian
contracts in medieval and Renaissance Tuscany. Her recent work includes “A
Tale of ‘Benevolent’ Governments: Private Credit Markets,
Public Finance, and the Role of Jewish Lenders in Medieval and Renaissance
Italy,” Journal of Economic History 60 (March 2000): 164-89 and “A
Loveless Economy? Intergenerational Altruism and the
Marriage Market in a Tuscan Town, 1415-1436,” Journal of Economic
History 59 (March 1999):
104-21.