Published by EH.NET (September 2001)
Philip Parker, Physioeconomics: The Basis for Long-Run Economic Growth.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000. xi + 315 pp. $29.95 (cloth), ISBN:
0-262-16194-X.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Sylvain H. Boko, Department of Economics, Wake Forest
University.
This book offers a unique approach to explaining differences in growth
performance across countries. The approach is based on the so-called
“equatorial paradox,” the observation that the closer a country is to the
equator the more likely it will have lower than average consumption per
capita. The author argues that the latitude of a country is the main
determinant of its inhabitants’ “homeostatic utility,” which, in turn, is
determined by the laws of physics (thermodynamics), and the brain’s
hypothalamus, a major regulator of homeostasis. For Parker, each country has a
natural homeostatic steady state, governed by physioeconomics. Further, he
proposes that a country’s economic performance should be gauged “not by its
absolute level of income or consumption, but rather by how far it is from
[its] homeostatic steady state” (p. ix). With respect to the empirical
application of these ideas, Parker proposes four innovative approaches, the
results of which are sometimes unexpected.
The first idea stems from the observation that international economic data are
spatially correlated. As is well known, failure to account for these
correlations results in inefficient parameter estimates, biased estimates and
bad inference. Attempts to correct for such autocorrelation or serial
autocorrelation problems through the inclusion of dummy variables in
traditional growth models have proven “disappointing” from the author’s point
of view. A proposed solution is a sample matching approach, which consists of
clustering countries based on their “physioeconomic dispositions” (p 212).
Within each cluster, countries are then ranked by various measures of
performance, allowing for standard econometric modeling to be applied. The
approach is said to effectively eliminate spatial correlations, easily
revealing the successes and failures of each country’s policies relative to
other members of the cluster. One shortcoming of this approach is that it
provides only limited insight into the dynamics of within-cluster performance.
To remedy this, Parker proposes “filtering” cross-country data “for exogenous
climatic variables, as one might deseasonalize times series data prior to
measuring the impact of policy” (p 216). The final residuals series after this
filtering is completed is termed a Relative Performance Index (RPI) by the
author. It is claimed that the RPI controls for exogenous factors that
underlie systematic differences in the steady state of homeostatic utility.
The higher the RPI, the better-ranked countries are. This procedure, when
applied to a cross-section of countries sometimes generated some highly
unexpected results. For example, according to this method, Burkina Faso “is an
above average performer, given its starting position, compared to the United
States^? [meaning that] it has been better at generating more income given its
steady-state endowments than the United States with its endowments” (p. 225).
This is not a conclusion that one would expect to obtain from traditional
growth models.
The author points out that the filtering procedure lacks utility maximization
and “homeostatic comfort” as a central notion. Thus, an alternative solution
is to use “local performance measures.” Roughly, this method calls for the
determination of local (country-specific) and “unambiguous” measures of
physical consumption (food, housing, clothing, transportation, energy and
various forms of entertainment) that is required to establish human comfort,
this being determined by the country’s “thermodynamic disposition.” A relative
performance index is then derived by dividing actual per capita income by the
income required for a “decent standard of living.” On the basis of this
measure, a country is ranked as a high performer when it has been able to
generate average incomes that are higher than the minimal requirements for
the country’s specifically determined “decent living conditions.” The
application of this methodology to a cross-section of countries also reveals
surprising results. For instance, contrary to the popular notion in the
literature, some of the highest performing countries (with Gabon as a prime
example) are in Africa.
The fourth idea advanced in the book, and the least convincing, is to ask
groups of selected respondents from various countries, what income levels they
believe would be necessary in their respective countries to achieve the same
level of utility as in some selected base country (Germany for example). The
author terms this method “direct inspection.” Groups of World Bank or IMF
types, MBA students, and economists from various points on the globe are asked
to answer this question. The apparently consistent result is that the
utility-equalizing income levels indicated by those who originate from hotter
countries are significantly lower than those indicated by respondents
originating from colder countries. It is a rather “obtuse” methodology as
recognized by the author himself, and one that seems forced. The most glaring
shortcoming of this method is that it polls people or groups of people who are
not representative of the average person in their countries of origin, and
may have a distorted notion of what income that average person would need to
achieve the same level of utility as other countries. However, the results do
seem to corroborate the hypothesis — i.e., warmer countries have lower
requirements for physical consumption to maintain their steady-state level of
homeostatic utility than colder countries — that the book purports to test.
The book ends with long-term predictions with respect to various measures of
development. Generally, the predictions are that longevity, literacy,
population growth, and migration, as well as the adoption of liberal political
and economic institutions, will converge in the long run (by the end of the
twenty-first century), both in terms of mean and dispersion, across all
countries. However, consumption patterns will remain divergent and
physioeconomic factors will generate most variances in the long run. It is
somewhat disappointing that most of the arguments used to support these
predictions are intuitive. There is no treatment of the dynamics that will
determine the convergence or divergence of the different measures considered
in this analysis.
In the end, the book makes a valiant effort in its attempts to find innovative
ways to measure the relative performance of countries. If one were to agree
with the book’s contention that a country’s latitude, through the laws of
thermodynamics, determines its population’s homeostatic consumption level and
utility, then this implies a major shift in development policy. Lower income
countries need not emulate higher income countries with respect to consumption
levels, since the former group needs lowers levels of physical consumption to
achieve the same level of utility as the latter group. The policy focus ought
to be to invest in education, health and infrastructure to assure that for
each country, the inhabitants have achieved a comfort level that is at least
equal to the minimum required level of consumption, determined locally on the
basis of physioeconomics. As suggested by the author, “the World Bank and
similar institutions should invest greater resources in estimating the real
income required to maintain human decency^? Abject poverty, whether in urban
America or rural Somalia, remains abject” (p. 234). This is a potentially
powerful line of research that can help to redirect countries’ resources to
more efficient and more effective usage by shifting the focus of development
policy from unattainable goals. As the opening chapters of the book
demonstrate however, the approach attempts to coordinate complex,
multidimensional and multidisciplinary issues and factors that affect human
behavior and human interaction, and perform economic analysis and predictions
on that basis. It is a difficult task that certainly requires further
development. Hopefully Physioeconomics will generate increased interest
in such an inquiry.
Sylvain H. Boko is currently completing a book on Decentralization and Reform
in Africa (Kluwer Academic Press, forthcoming). His articles include “The
Impact of International Agreements on Domestic Policy: An Analysis of Tariff
Policy in African Countries”(Atlantic Economic Journal, March 2001); and “A
New Look At Africa’s Growth Performance and Prospects for the 21st Century”
(in Ebere Onwudiwe and Minabere Ibelema, (eds), Afro-Optimism: Perspectives on
Africa’s Advances, Praeger. Forthcoming.)