Author(s): | Bhaduri, Amit |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Frost, Marcia J. |
Published by EH.NET (May 2001)
Amit Bhaduri, On the Border of Economic Theory and History. New Delhi:
Oxford University Press, 1999. 197 pp. $27.50 (cloth), ISBN: 0-19-564901-X.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Marcia J. Frost, Department of Economics, Grinnell
College.
Amit Bhaduri, Professor of Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaharlal Nehru
University (New Delhi), is a prolific author whose work may be familiar to
readers of the Cambridge Journal of Economics, the Economic
Journal, and the Indian Economic and Social History Review. On
the Border of Economic Theory and History is a compilation of ten essays
organized into two sections. All but one of the five “Essays on Traditional
Agriculture” were previously published in English between 1986 and 1993. Three
of the “Essays on Capitalism” were written for this book; two were previously
published in unidentified French and Turkish journals. Most essays are
followed by a short bibliography, and there is a seven-page keyword and person
index.
The five “Essays on Traditional Agriculture” all share a common ideology,
theme and method. The former is clearly indicated by the essay titles: “A
Study in Agricultural Backwardness under Semi-Feudalism,” “The Evolution of
Land Relations in Eastern India under British Rule,” “Class Relations and the
Pattern of Accumulation in an Agrarian Economy,” “Forced Commerce and Agrarian
Growth,” and “Economic Power and Productive Efficiency in Traditional
Agriculture.” Bhaduri’s common theme focuses on what he alternatively terms
semi-feudal, underdeveloped or traditional agriculture which he characterizes
by the exploitation of agricultural workers (who hold little or no land) by
the landed class through sharecropping and usurious credit arrangements.
According to Bhaduri, because the landlord-cum-moneylender earns income
(extracts surplus) both from his share of the agricultural output and the high
interest on consumption loans he extends his sharecroppers, the landlord has a
reduced incentive to encourage the adoption of technological improvements in
agriculture. Technological innovation, by increasing the income of
sharecroppers, reduces borrowing to meet consumption needs and thus reduces
the landlord-cum-moneylender’s income from his credit extension activities. If
the reduction in interest income exceeds the increase in crop share income,
the landlord-cum-moneylender will not innovate, and agricultural progress
will be stymied. In addition Bhaduri argues there are no gains from trade for
the exploited, since sharecroppers are coerced by their usurious credit
agreements to sell their share at harvest when prices are low and then buy
months later when prices are high and credit must again be sought.
Bhaduri’s theoretical exercises are thorough and, given his assumptions, his
conclusions are reasonable. What’s lacking, however, is empirical backing of
his basic assumptions, empirical testing of his models and concreteness in
time and space. Why is it that only landlords are agents and sharecroppers are
precluded from innovation in his model? Where is the empirical evidence of the
reasonableness of this fundamental assumption of his models? Who comprises the
landlord class and is class an appropriate characterization of post-zamindari
agrarian relations in Bengal, let alone elsewhere in India?
The second set of “Essays on Capitalism” shares no common theme beyond
Bhaduri’s concluding statement “Lying on the border of ‘theory’ and ‘history’,
economic analysis cannot escape the influence of the arbitrary initial
conditions inherited from history” (p. 189). The first of these essays “Why
Factories?” examines the tension of cooperation and conflict between modes of
production as labor productivity enhancing investments shifted production from
home to factory. It’s an interesting essay and reminds us of the
interdependence of both modes of production for long periods of time. In “Some
Lessons from the Two Economic Systems” Bhaduri explores why socialist systems
collapsed at the end of the twentieth century, and tells a now common story of
the failure of labor productivity to rise in the long run and the rigidity of
a system without political and economic mechanisms to self-correct. In “The
Political Economy of Social Democracy” his goal is to explain the evolution of
economic ideology as political institutions have changed through the expansion
of universal suffrage, the adoption of full-employment and welfare
Keynesianism, and open trade has made “the autonomous conduct of economic
policies by the nation-state, not only difficult, but also exceptionally
risky” (p. 157). “Dangers and Opportunity of Globalization for Developing
Countries” briefly traces the dismantling of regulations on international
capital flows and argues for IMF flexibility as developing nations face acute
difficulty in meeting international payment obligations. His final essay
“Reflections on the Economic Role of the Transformational State” reflects on
the important role the state played in the evolution of market economies and
must play in transition economies in defining rules and providing public
goods.
Marcia Frost is Assistant Professor of Economics at Grinnell College and
author of “Coping with Scarcity: Wild Foods and Common Lands: Kheda District
(Gujarat, India), 1824/5,” The Indian Economic and Social History
Review 37:3 (2000).
Subject(s): | Economywide Country Studies and Comparative History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | Asia |
Time Period(s): | General or Comparative |