Author(s): | Surdam, David G. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Ransom, Roger L. |
Published by EH.NET (November 2001)
David G. Surdam, Northern Naval Superiority and the Economics of the
American Civil War. Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 2001.
xiv + 286 pp. $34.95 (cloth), ISBN: 1-57003-407-9.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Roger L. Ransom, Department of History, University of
California, Riverside.
Historians have argued for years whether the effort of the Union Navy to cut
off trade to the Confederacy during the Civil War was an effective weapon that
hastened the end of the war. At present it appears that there is still some
question whether the glass is half full — or is it half empty? Those who see
the glass as half full point to the enormous fall in commerce during the war
along with the evidence of shortages in the Confederacy; those who see it as
half empty argue that it was not until mid 1863 that the blockade was fully
in place, and even then enough blockade runners got through to provide the
South with the essential military supplies to carry on the war. In this
well-researched study of Union naval activities during the war, David Surdam
seeks to provide an answer to this enduring puzzle by examining the problem
from an economist’s perspective. Surdam begins by pointing out that counting
the number of ships and tons of supplies that did or did not “get through” the
blockade is an inadequate way to measure of the success or failure of the
closing of Confederate ports. “The focus on imports,” he notes “has been
almost myopic and misses what may have been two of the blockade’s most
important achievements: disrupting intraregional trade and denying the
Confederacy badly needed revenue from exporting raw cotton and other staple
products” (p.6).
Part I of the book presents an overview of the Southern economy on the eve of
the Civil War. Surdam provides ample quantitative evidence to demonstrate that
the South was more than capable of producing enough food to support itself
during a war — a result that will hardly surprise those familiar with earlier
debates on antebellum Southern self-sufficiency. The problem, Surdam points
out, is that the food production was either scattered over large areas, or —
in the case of meat — concentrated in areas that were remote from the scene
of fighting. In normal times, a combination of coastal and river traffic could
move supplies to central markets and on to their final destination. A point
that is often ignored by those who stress the importance of smuggling military
goods into the South during the war is that the blockade not only made it
difficult to carry on foreign commerce from Southern ports; it also shut down
the coastal trade that had been so active in antebellum times. Without that
water transport, the Southern rail system had to pick up the slack. It was
not equal to the task. The result, argues Surdam, was a serious problem of
moving goods within the CSA.
Part II of the book examines the effect that this disruption of trade had on
the Confederate economy and military effort. An important element of Surdam’s
argument is that he includes the Union control of New Orleans and the
Mississippi Valley as part of the “blockade.” Chapters 3 and 4 examine the
extent to which Union forces were able to seriously restrict the flow of meat
from the trans-Mississippi area, thereby creating severe shortages of meat in
the Eastern Confederacy. There is no question that access to the coastal trade
and inland waterways could have alleviated this problem. Chapter 5 presents
an excellent analysis of the shortcomings of the Southern rail system in
meeting this challenge. This is the best chapter of the book. Surdam clearly
shows how the Union Navy’s blockade and control of the Mississippi Valley
strained an already overtaxed rail system in the South to the breaking point.
The impact of the blockade was two-fold. On the one hand, the closing of water
transport meant that there was increased traffic on a rail system that was not
designed for heavy shipments of through freight. Nor was the Southern rail
system built to handle shipments along an east-west axis rather than
north-south axis. Increased traffic meant that rolling stock and equipment
wore out faster. The second impact of the blockade on the transportation
system was to eliminate the possibility of importing materials that would
allow the railroads to be maintained — or in some cases to have new railroads
built. The result was that rail service deteriorated steadily throughout the
war and problems of supply increased everywhere.
Chapters 6 and 7 examine in greater detail the effects of this collapse of the
transportation system on military and civilian efforts to support the war
together with a brief examination of the supply situation in Virginia in
Chapter 9. There are no surprises here; my main complaint is that Surdam
devotes too little space (a total of twenty pages for all three chapters) to
problems that are central to the debates on the effects of the blockade. The
major thrust of his argument is that the blockade raised costs of
transportation to the point where it cost $2 to get $1 of imports. In an
economy that depended on imported goods for some of its basic needs, this is a
serious problem. Yet Surdam says very little about the role of the blockade in
adding to inflationary pressures, and apart from some anecdotes from reports
of riots and personal hardships he does not explore the effects on civilian
morale of the reduced supply of imported goods whose availability Southerners
had taken for granted before the war. As Avner Offer has pointed out with
regard to the effects of the Allied blockade of Germany in World War I, the
rapid elimination of goods that were an important part of people’s consumption
package can force a drastic change in consumption patterns that eventually had
a deleterious effect on the morale at home (The First World War: An
Agrarian Interpretation, 1989).
Surdam presents a convincing case that there were serious problems of supply
within the CSA during the war. My sense is that looking further into these
problems would reveal that the total impact of the transportation collapse on
civilian life was even greater than the picture that Surdam portrays. Yet
there remains the question: How great was the role of the blockade in creating
this problem? Granted, taking away the coastal shipping hindered movements of
supplies. But Surdam admits that even had there been no blockade the CSA would
have encountered extreme difficulties in meeting demands for shipping goods
to all parts of the country. And the armies posed a special problem for even a
well-developed transportation network. Each of the two major armies of the CSA
was a “mobile population center” of 40,000 to 90,000 people (p. 98). Even
without a blockade feeding the Armies would have been a challenge for the
Southern transportation network — a situation that on two occasions caused
Lee to take his army into the North for forage — with disastrous
consequences. What emerges from the discussion of this part of the book is the
crucial role of the Union Navy in greatly compounding the problems of the
Southern transportation problems by capturing New Orleans early in the war.
Because Texas and Arkansas were the major meat producers in the CSA, the
interdiction of trade across the Mississippi created a serious shortage of
meat for Southern Armies throughout the war.
Part III of the book moves on to the question of “King Cotton” and the efforts
of the CSA to maximize the earning power of their staple crop. “Cotton
revenues,” claims Surdam, “remained the Confederacy’s best economic asset, but
realization of that asset depended upon the South’s ability to properly play
its cotton card in the face of Northern naval superiority” (p.132). Surdam
begins with a discussion in Chapter 9 of how the South could have manipulated
the supply of cotton to its advantage by placing an export tax on the staple
and perhaps encouraging producers to cut back on cotton production. Whatever
their theoretical appeal as economic policies, neither of these proposals made
a great deal of political sense. Surdam himself admits that efforts to impose
an export tax met with little enthusiasm in the Confederate Congress. Efforts
to control exports offered little basis for confidence that the CSA would play
its “cotton card” right. The one effort to manipulate cotton supply — the
embargo of 1861 — produced a miscalculation that threatened to deprive the
CSA of its chance to get cotton to European markets even before the blockade
became effective. Surdam correctly notes that the effect of the embargo was
not as great as often believed, inasmuch as the 1860 crop had already been
shipped and the 1861 crop had not yet been harvested (pp.161-62). Nonetheless,
a perusal of Confederate policy towards “manipulating” cotton hardly leads one
to the conclusion that this is a policy area with great possibilities for
success, and by the middle of 1862 the question was rendered moot by the
increasing effectiveness of the Blockade.
In Chapter 10 Surdam engages in a prolonged discussion of the future of world
cotton market in the period after 1860. While the econometric analysis
presented in this chapter might be of interest to those interested in what has
been a spirited debate over the stagnation of cotton prices after the Civil
War, it seems to me that this discussion is largely irrelevant to an
assessment of the effects of the Northern blockade in 1862-65. As Surdam
points out, the effect of the blockade was to drive up the price of cotton in
Britain. But since the blockade also denied cotton shipments to Europe, the
Confederates were unable to reap the potential revenue such exports might have
brought in the form of both foreign exchange and export taxes. Surdam contends
that had those cotton exports been shipped, the South could have paid for
imports needed in the war effort, and coupled with clever management of the
CSA finances, obtained revenues from export taxes to finance the war. He
regards this as a “catastrophic loss” of revenues to the South that crippled
their military effort.
This is an interesting argument, but I do not find it convincing. There is no
question that the South would have been better off if it were free to ship
cotton to Europe. But I would argue that the inability to ship cotton exports
to Europe was not as “catastrophic” as Surdam suggests. The South was still
able to play a “cotton card” in Europe without having to actually ship the
cotton. The Confederate government raised money abroad by issuing bonds based
on the expectation that the existing supply of cotton could be shipped to
Europe as soon as the war ended. The success of the “Erlanger Bonds,” which
were backed by cotton, underscored this point. They actually held their value
better than bonds backed by gold. In short, Confederates could and did
mortgage the cotton crops to pay for the war — but they still needed to win
the war! The role played by the Blockade in disrupting the Southern economy
outlined in Part II of this book, rather than the inability of the South to
ship cotton to Europe was what ultimately worked to defeat the Confederate war
effort. One of the issues Surdam does not raise in connection with the
“cotton card” was the possibility that Southern producers continued to produce
cotton long after the blockade had made such production almost worthless. The
loss in manpower employed in useless cotton production was probably a more
severe loss to the Confederate war effort than the loss of revenue from a
cotton export tax that was never collected.
One of the ironies of the Union naval blockade was that the North cut itself
off from the supply of raw cotton. In Chapter 13 Surdam presents a brief
analysis of the Northern efforts to obtain cotton through the blockade. This
was a fairly easy task once Union forces occupied New Orleans and secured
Memphis on the Mississippi. Both sides gained in this trade, and each had
difficulty weighing net gains. As Surdam points out, Lincoln recognized this
and when asked what his policy was with regard to trading cotton for supplies
with the rebels he replied “My policy is to have no policy!” (p. 202). After
noting the advantages to both sides, Surdam concludes that “it would be unfair
to expect that either government would have maximized the potential gains”
from the exchange of cotton.
In the final chapter of the book, Surdam notes that the U.S. government
commissioned 700 vessels and spent $567 million — or about 8 percent of the
total expenditures of the war — on the navy (p. 206). He then raises the
obvious question that should be asked by an economist: Was such an elaborate
blockade necessary to cripple the South? Clearly, the South was harmed by the
blockade. The real question is therefore whether a lesser effort might have
produced almost as powerful a result. We noted above that Surdam’s argument on
the centrality of the Mississippi Valley suggests that the capture of New
Orleans by itself was a crippling blow that could not be offset by a different
pattern of shipments within the South, and a blockade of several major gulf
ports would have been sufficient to virtually shut down the cotton trade. But
there remains the blockade’s success in shutting down the coastal trade. Just
how successful this was can be seen in the numbers on ships that successfully
ran the blockade. Over the course of the war, blockade runners made 5,400
successful runs. However, to put this number in perspective we should note
that 3,500 of those were in the first year of the war, and that before the
war New Orleans alone had an average of more than 1,900 vessels enter annually
(p.5). My assessment of Surdam’s analysis of the strain this put on the
transportation system is that, even allowing for some ambiguity as to how much
of the disruption was due to the blockade, he is correct in his conclusion
that “for the resources expended, the blockade appears to have been a
worthwhile investment” (p. 209).
For those interested in studying the blockade or the economy of the South
during the war, this book is a worthwhile investment. In addition to the
compelling argument that the transportation infrastructure of the South was
crippled by the strain of the Northern naval blockade, the book includes a
wealth of well-organized data and several excellent maps of the Confederate
transportation system. And, for those who wish to explore some of the issues
in greater depth, the author has added appendices dealing with the estimates
of meat supply, the potential revenue from raw cotton in the CSA and three
appendices on the demand for cotton in the U.S. and Britain.
Roger Ransom is author of “The Economics of the Civil War” in EH.Net’s
Encyclopedia of Economic and Business History.
http://eh.net/encyclopedia/ransom.civil.war.us.php
Subject(s): | Transport and Distribution, Energy, and Other Services |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 19th Century |