Author(s): | Spafford, Shirley |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Neill, Robin F. |
Published by EH.NET (September 2000)
Shirley Spafford, No Ordinary Academics: Economics and Political Science at
the University of Saskatchewan, 1910-1960. Toronto: University of Toronto
Press, 2000. ix + 272 pp. $45 (cloth), ISBN: 0-8020-4437-9.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Robin F. Neill, Department of Economics, University of
Prince Edward Island and Carleton University.
In the words of W. C. Murray, President of the University of Saskatchewan from
its founding in 1910 until his retirement in 1937, his economists were to be
“no ordinary academics” because, following practice at the University of
Wisconsin (as Murray saw it), they were to serve the economic and political
interests of the farmers who, ultimately, paid the university’s bills. There
was little, if any, institutional and personnel difference between economics
and political science at the university, in part because political science had
yet to identify itself as a separate social science, and in part because the
mission of economics at Saskatchewan was to shape national and provincial
policy in the interests of Western Canada.
No Ordinary Academics is well written in the tradition of Canadian
academic biography. Shirley Spafford is to be congratulated on a contribution
to the field of Canadian Intellectual History. Still, some caveats for the
would-be reader are in order.
The book is not a work in the history of ideas. Its approach is personal and
institutional. With the exception of a few pages describing a strong element in
the historiographical stance of Vernon Fowke, the reader is left with just a
suggestion of what the content of Economics and Political Science was on the
Saskatoon campus. Classroom economics was what it was elsewhere, but what it
was elsewhere is not revealed. It seems to have been unimportant to the people
involved. Having the correct policy stance, one consistent with the views of
the agrarian community to be served, was more important. Political science was
constitutional history and a smattering of the classics in political
philosophy. Competence in advanced neoclassical theory, or, later, in Keynesian
theory, in mathematical economics, or econometrics was not a requirement,
though it was increasingly present in the department. Of course, there were
courses in introductory economics, money and banking, international trade, and
public finance.
It was important for the faculty to be adequately schooled in economics. Until
Murray resigned in 1937, to be Scots was also important. To be Scots and
Presbyterian was to be among the chosen.
Murray, in the course of a long interview, showed only lukewarm interest in
hiring him until it came out that [R. McG.] Dawson was Nova Scotian, and proud
of it, at which point Murray, whose fondness for Nova Scotia had never
diminished, was completely won over (p. 115).
The book has some tantalizing interest for the historian of economic thought in
Canada. For example, we all know that H. A. Innis, at Toronto in the 1930s, was
less than accepting of the socialist historian, Frank Underhill. What I expect
few of us knew, and Spafford has revealed, is that Underhill, while a member of
the Department of Economics and Political Science at Saskatchewan, “published a
searing criticism of Innis’s book on the fur trade.” But here we experience the
shortcoming of Spafford’s book. She offers not a clue as to the views expressed
by Innis or Underhill in this matter, and she does not provide detailed
bibliographical references to the literature in question. Indeed, the book has
thirty-nine pages of endnotes, citing mostly other biographies, personal
papers, and letters, and it has an excellent nineteen-page index, but it has no
bibliography or list of references. The present reviewer would have benefited
from the in-text, general references to the works of Fowke and Timlin in the
chapter dealing with their contributions, but considerable additional digging
would have been necessary before the newly revealed items could have been added
to attempted definitive lists of their publications. Spafford recounts in some
detail the personal conflicts and power struggles in the department, but, some
intriguing clues aside, she throws no light on their doctrinal dimensions.
Weak with respect to ideas and bibliography, No Ordinary Academics is
strong with respect to personal, social, and institutional history. Economics
at Saskatchewan was heavily influenced by the preferences of the self-selecting
elite that shaped Canadian universities, especially between 1910 and 1940. The
account presents an impressive list of outstanding Canadian social scientists
(which is not to say economists, as that term is now understood) whose early
careers included a stay in the department at Saskatchewan. In the end, however,
given the financial constraints on the university in the 1930s, it was
home-grown scholars, influenced by conditions on the Prairies, that made a
distinctively western contribution to economic analysis of the Canadian case.
(For the intellectual substance of their contribution see R. F. Neill,
“Economic Historiography in the 1950s: the Saskatchewan School,” Journal of
Canadian Studies, Vol. 34, 1999, pp. 243-260.)
No Ordinary Academics is an account of selected external factors shaping
economics at the University of Saskatchewan between 1910 and 1960. The
principal members of what elsewhere has been called the Saskatchewan School —
Vernon Fowke, George Britnell, Mabel Timlin, and Ken Buckley — were no
ordinary academics. From Spafford’s history we know that they were idealists,
even romantics, who put economics at the service of their altogether honorable
social goals. Their rewards were largely non-monetary; working as they did for
their students, their associations, and their governments, provincial and
national, frequently at their own expense, and despite appallingly low
remuneration.
Subject(s): | History of Economic Thought; Methodology |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |