Published by EH.NET (July 2001)
Edward J. Balleisen, Navigating Failure: Bankruptcy and Commercial Society
in Antebellum America. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
2001. xv + 322 pp. $49.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-8078-2600-6; $18.95 (paper), ISBN:
0-8078-4916-2.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Bradley A. Hansen, Department of Economics, Mary
Washington College.
The stories of successful entrepreneurs play a prominent role in American
economic history. Edward Balleisen reminds us that throughout history many
more businesses have failed than have succeeded, and that to understand
American economic history we need to understand how people have dealt with
commercial failure. Using a wide range of sources he attempts to reconstruct
the experience of commercial failure in antebellum America. Although the
intended audience appears to be primarily historians — Balleisen is assistant
professor of history at Duke University — economists should also read
Navigating Failure. Underlying the entire study is a concern with how
institutions affect entrepreneurship. Laws and norms related to credit always
involve a balancing act. If they are too lenient there is insufficient
incentive to repay and credit will be in short supply. If they are too harsh
entrepreneurs will be less likely to take risks. For those who would prefer to
take a more quantitative approach, Balleisen’s work also points the way toward
an underutilized source for economic and business history.
Though people now take bankruptcy for granted, for most of the nineteenth
century there was no bankruptcy law in the United States. When Congress passed
a bankruptcy law following the Panics of 1837 and 1839, insolvent businessmen
flocked to the courts to seek a discharge. In the two years that the law was
in effect over 40,000 people petitioned for bankruptcy. Balleisen begins his
study of commercial failure with a largely unexamined source: the records of
bankruptcy proceedings in the Southern District of New York under the 1841
Bankruptcy Act.
Balleisen readily admits that his sample of cases is not random. He is less
interested in rigorous statistical analysis than in constructing a “collective
biography.” His selection of cases is determined by the availability of
records that enable him to track the individual’s path to bankruptcy and then
to follow events after bankruptcy. Among the sources he utilizes are credit
reports, newspaper articles, court records, and local histories. Balleisen
sifted through such records for over 500 bankrupts. He combines this
collective biography with extensive reading of the popular literature. In the
story that emerges he emphasizes three themes: the changing meanings of
failure and economic independence, the importance of familial ties, and the
impact of widespread economic calamity.
He finds that many of these men (only nine of the bankrupts in his sample were
women) were brought to bankruptcy by the usual problems of new businesses:
lack of experience, inadequate capital, and failure to keep adequate accounts.
A few were brought to ruin by outright speculation, drinking, or living beyond
their means. Some, on the other hand, were relatively capable business people
brought down by the financial panics and depression of the late 1830s.
After bankruptcy, most sought to return to the ranks of business owners.
Balleisen’s conclusions regarding who was able to successfully return to the
ranks of the self-employed supports the work of Naomi Lamoreaux and others on
the importance of connections, particularly family connections, for merchants
and manufacturers. The ability to utilize family ties to reestablish credit
was often crucial to a successful comeback. There were some substitutes for
familial connections, such as valuable knowledge or skills. For example, R.
Hoe and Co., manufacturers of high quality circular saws and printing presses,
shut down for only one week and received new lines of credit as they were
going through bankruptcy. Some people were actually able to use their
experience of commercial failure to their advantage in such fields as credit
reporting.
Balleisen also uses the popular literature of the time to relate changes in
the nature of commercial failure to changing attitudes toward economic
independence and economic failure. At the beginning of the nineteenth century,
sermons, short stories and novels extolled the kind of economic independence
that comes from owning one’s own business. At the same time they tended to
portray the failure to pay one’s debts as a moral failure. One cartoon from
the 1850s shows an insolvent businessman taking his morning walk while hiding
behind his wife’s skirts. Balleisen argues that the financial calamities of
the nineteenth century gradually altered people’s attitudes toward commercial
failure. People began to perceive that even men who had acted prudently might
become unable to pay their debts through no fault of their own. Although
self-employment remained the ideal, some people began to see a certain kind of
economic independence in salaried employment for a stable company, a freedom
from the constant risk of ruin faced by entrepreneurs.
One aspect of the story that might be a little confusing for those who have
not spent a great deal of time considering commercial failure is the use of
the terms failure and bankruptcy. In chapters three and four, Balleisen
provides an excellent description of bankruptcy law and how it differed from
state debtor-creditor laws, but he also chooses to be consistent with
colloquial usage and use the terms failure, bankruptcy and insolvency
interchangeably to refer to someone who cannot pay their debts. In legal
discussions, however, bankruptcy refers specifically to federal law dealing
with insolvency. Bankruptcy provides a pro rata distribution of a debtor’s
assets and a discharge for the bankrupt. State laws typically distributed an
insolvent debtor’s assets on a first-come- first-served basis and did not
provide a discharge. The term commercial failure, as Dun and Bradstreet use
it, refers to businesses that have been discontinued and failed to pay all
their debts. It does not count the many businesses that close with a loss to
their owners but not their creditors.
Making a distinction between bankruptcy, commercial failure and discontinuance
is more than just a matter of semantics; it emphasizes the extent of economic
failure. Of the businesses that are discontinued, only a small portion fail to
pay their debts. Of the businesses that fail to pay their debts only a small
portion end up in bankruptcy. Bankruptcy cases are just the tip of the iceberg
of economic failure. It would be interesting to see how a collective
biography of bankrupts compares to a collective biography of those who became
insolvent but did not declare bankruptcy, or a collective biography of those
who closed up shop but managed to pay their debts. It would, of course, also
be interesting to see how Balleisen’s collective biography would compare with
one of bankrupts under the 1867 bankruptcy law or the 1898 bankruptcy law.
Edward Balleisen has made a considerable contribution to our understanding of
commercial failure, but he would probably be among the first to admit that
much of the story remains to be told.
Bradley A. Hansen is assistant professor of economics at Mary Washington
College. His publications include “The People’s Welfare and the Origins of
Corporate Reorganization: The Wabash Receivership Reconsidered,” Business
History Review (Autumn 2000); and “Commercial Associations and the
Creation of a National Economy: The Demand For A Federal Bankruptcy Law,”
Business History Review (Spring 1998).