Author(s): | Hatcher, John Bailey, Mark |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Richardson, Gary |
Published by EH.NET (March 2003)
John Hatcher and Mark Bailey, Modelling the Middle Ages: The History and
Theory of England’s Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2001. xiii + 254 pp. $49.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-19-924411-1; $19.95 (paperback),
ISBN: 0-19-924412-X.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Gary Richardson, Department of Economics, University of
California, Irvine.
Modelling the Middle Ages, by John Hatcher and Mark Bailey, provides a
cogent and comprehensive survey of the history and economics of late medieval
England and an invaluable survey of the history of thought concerning those
topics. Scholars interested in these issues should read this book. It will be
especially valuable for graduate and undergraduate economic history courses,
where I expect it to be widely adopted, and for researchers, like myself, with
an interest in medieval England but who had to learn the material on their own,
because they studied at institutions that lacked leading (or any) scholars in
the field. I base my strong recommendation on three features of the text:
First, the book is insightful. It demystifies the beliefs underlying the
arguments of most economic historians — beliefs derived from intellectual
foundations established in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries by Adam
Smith, Thomas Malthus, David Ricardo, Karl Marx, and other eminent scholars. It
explains how and why the work of those intellectual forefathers generated three
grand explanatory models, “population and resources,” “class power and property
relations,” and “commercialization,” and how those models influenced debates
among historians and social scientists concerning the causes and consequences
of economic development during the Middle Ages.
Second, the book is useful, in the most practical sense of the term. It
summarizes two hundred years of scholarly literature in a few hundred pages
while building a framework, a lexicon, and a syntax that will allow scholars to
compare and contrast their ideas more precisely than they currently can. It
will have wide applications in other fields, such as global history,
particularly global history, where similar models form the foundation of
similar debates.
Third, the book is clear, lucid, and accurate. In some cases, the book explains
author’s ideas better than the original expositors did themselves. The clarity
of the prose and the organization of the argument assure the material will be
accessible to students at all levels.
The foreword and introduction establish the motives of the authors and sketch
an outline of their argument. The authors hope to fulfill a “pressing need of
undergraduate students studying the medieval economy for an introduction to the
theory and practice behind the grand models of development which dominate the
subject (p. vii).” As I mentioned earlier, they more than accomplish that goal.
The authors also hope to contribute to the ongoing scholarly debates concerning
the economic development of medieval England. They plan to compare and contrast
the intellectual and empirical content of the methods and models used to study
medieval English economic history and in doing so shed light on the advantages
and disadvantages of each method as well as advance our knowledge of the Middle
Ages. They also accomplish this goal, as my description of the remainder of the
book, and hopefully your reading of the text, should demonstrate.
Chapter 1, Methods and Models, explains “why the medieval period has proved so
attractive to the builders of historical models, and theorizing so attractive
to medieval historians (p. 3).” The Middle Ages lasted for more than five
centuries. During that long era, transformations occurred in almost every area
of economic and social life. Merely describing these changes is a challenging
task. “Historians cannot hope to describe, analyze, and explain them by
gathering and narrating factual information alone (p. 4).” They must choose to
present certain facts and materials but not others. Their emphasize depends
upon their point of view, their prior beliefs, and the point which they wish to
make. Theory and speculation are therefore indispensable ingredients of any
grand survey. They impose a degree of coherence and clarity and force scholars
to fit the facts into a manageable working framework. In this way, order can be
imposed upon the chaos of vast numbers of pieces of information and answers
formulated to crucial questions. In addition, abstract concepts and formal
models help scholars explain why things happened as they did and what might
have happened in counterfactual cases. Explaining such things requires more
than mere narration. Historical changes lasting several centuries and
penetrating all spheres of economic, social, and political activity were the
culmination of an infinite number of individual events. No one can describe
them all. Comprehending them requires analysis, a systematic approach to the
material, the sorting and grading of information, and the weighing of the
relative merits of different concepts. Models, in other words, are needed to
seek the reasons behind vast historical processes such as the rise and decline
of serfdom and feudalism, the rise of the money economy and capitalism, the
rise and contraction of economic activity, and the growth of urbanization and
industrialization.
Chapter 2, Population and Resources, focuses on the first of the grand
supermodels, and the ways in which assumptions influence its results and in
which it impinges on historical analysis “in both a helpful and harmful
manner.” The population and resource model, also known as the demographic or
Malthusian model, stems from a core set of simple economic relationships. The
productivity of agriculture depends upon the relative scarcity of the two prime
factors of production: land and labor. As addition units of one input are
employed while the others are held constant, the output generated by each
additional unit will eventually fall (diminishing returns). Thus, when land is
abundant relative to labor, the productivity of the land will be low. The
productivity of labor will be high. Products of the land, like foodstuffs and
raw materials such as leather, wool, and wood, will be inexpensive. Wages will
be high. When labor is abundant relative to land, the productivity of the land
will be high. The productivity of labor will be low. Food and rents will be
expensive. Real wages will fall. There is clear potential for applying such
basic supply and demand analysis to conditions prevailing in medieval England.
“There is abundant evidence to show that over the longer term there was a
strong correlation between rising population, on the one hand, and increasing
land values and agricultural prices, and falling real wages, and, on the other,
between declining population, falling prices and land values, and rising real
wages. By this analysis the Middle Ages falls into two sharply contrasting
periods; with the broad experience of much of the era up until the fourteenth
century conforming to the former set of circumstances, and the later
characteristics persisting throughout much of the late fourteenth and fifteenth
centuries” (pp. 22-23).
Chapter 3, Class Power and Property Relations, examines the second grand
supermodel, which begins with the presumption that the keys to understanding
the economic development lie in the social relations and political and legal
institutions of society. Of particular importance are the “relations between
the leading classes and in developments of what are termed the ‘mode of
production'” (p. 67). The most popular models of this type are those
constructed by Karl Marx and his intellectual descendants. For Marxists,
“history is a dialectical process in which the future is shaped by the present,
just as the present was shaped by the past, and each distinct era of human
development — ancient, oriental, feudal, capitalist — generates from within
itself the conditions which will ultimately transform it” (pp. 67-8). Marxists
focus their attention on a limited range of issues, particularly relations and
conflicts among social classes as well as the mode, means, and relations of
production, as the main agents of social and economic change and development.
Thus, the dynamic for the transformation of medieval society lay primarily in
the relationship between lords and peasants, who were the two principle classes
of feudal society. The relationship was inevitably one of conflict, due to the
opposing interests of landlord and tenant, and eventually resulted in a ‘crisis
of feudalism,’ whose “onset is usually located in the late thirteenth and early
fourteenth centuries” (p. 71). At that time, the increasingly excessive
depredations of the landlord class undermined agricultural productivity,
plunged the peasantry into poverty, and inspired them to struggle against the
exploitative social system.
Chapter 4, Commercialization, Markets, and Technology, focuses on commercial
activity and technical progress. The bulk of the space is devoted to the
rapidly expanding evidentiary base and to the discussion of ways in which
markets and technology could overcome Malthusian, Ricardian, and Marxist
constraints on economic development. There are two basic theories. Improvements
in agriculture — such as improving land management, crop rotation, and
selective breeding of crops and animals — raised the productivity of land and
labor. Urbanization and commercialization expanded the scope of the market, the
division of labor, and the wealth of nations.
Chapter 5, The Importance of Time and Place, explores the weaknesses of the
models discussed in the previous chapters from three different perspectives.
The first exposes the difficulties that emerge when the models are applied to
both the early and later Middle Ages. In each case, assumptions needed to apply
and conclusions drawn from the application of a model to the earlier era
conflict with those from the later period. The second reviews the wide range of
alternative models that have been proposed and which illuminate inadequacies in
existing models. The third tests the validity of the assumptions and methods of
each of the major supermodels by applying them to a particular test case: the
rise and decline of serfdom in medieval England.
Chapter 6, Beyond the Classic Supermodels, stresses the limitations of the
models described during the previous chapters. The principal flaws are their
neglect of social factors, institutions, historical contingency, and the
uncertainties inherent in individual behavior and group dynamics. The chapter
ends on a hopeful note, by suggesting ways in which the limitations of these
models might be overcome historically, empirically, and theoretically.
Overall, the book does an excellent job of accomplishing its two goals. The
first was to provide a clear and accessible introduction to the conceptual
frameworks that have dominated this field for many decades. The second was to
assess the strengths, weaknesses, relevance, and credibility of the models. The
book itself has many strengths and few weaknesses. I think that in the future
students interested in this topic will read it.
Gary Richardson is Assistant Professor of Economics at UC-Irvine. His
dissertation, “Social Change and Industrial Expansion before the Industrial
Revolution” was completed at the UC-Berkeley.
Subject(s): | History of Economic Thought; Methodology |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | Europe |
Time Period(s): | Medieval |