Author(s): | Mustafa, Sam A. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Wegge, Simone A. |
Published by EH.NET (October 2002)
Sam A. Mustafa, Merchants and Migrations: Germans and Americans in
Connection, 1776-1835. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate, 2001. xvii + 284 pp. $74.95
(cloth), ISBN: 0-7546-0590-6.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Simone A. Wegge, College of Staten Island – City
University of New York.
Mustafa’s Merchants and Migrations is a study about the development of
commercial activity between the Hanseatic ports of Bremen and Hamburg and
various North American ports during the post-colonial period. It is a
historical account of developing business activity between merchants or
Smithian economic growth on both sides of the ocean, as well as an account of
diplomatic efforts between the Hanseatic cities and the United States.
Migration per se is tangential to Mustafa’s tale, while political economy lies
at the center of it. Mustafa has used a wide variety of American and German
primary resources to explore this topic. These include the correspondence
records of merchants and diplomats, business records and contracts from a wide
variety of merchants, travel diaries of merchants and other private citizens,
the records and papers of various politicians, and consular papers. The author
has thus carefully considered various types of evidence to develop a picture of
the challenges businesspeople in the US and in the Hanse cities faced in
pursuing international trade.
The late eighteenth-century economies of Hanseatic cities like Bremen and
Hamburg, with ports easily accessible to the North Sea and Atlantic Ocean, were
involved in the business of exporting and importing goods between overseas
destinations. With the British navigation acts, however, any direct trade
between these German cities and American ports was difficult, except through
smugglers. All this changed with the American Revolution, after which Hanse
merchants were eager to develop commercial relationships with American
exporters and importers. Post-1776 trade between Bremen and Hamburg and the
American ports grew, slowly at first, but then in leaps and bounds during the
1790s. The Hanse cities became the second most important importer of goods from
the US in 1798, close behind Britain. In the years thereafter, under Napoleon’s
continental system, trade between the US and the main Hanseatic cities
collapsed, and the German port cities degenerated into places of squalor and
poverty. Mustafa provides extensive evidence of how much trade activity
deteriorated under French rule: a very large number of the Hanse merchants went
bankrupt, and only a very small amount of trade was transacted during the six
years of French occupation. With the end of French rule, trade between the
Hanse cities and the United States resumed, but only slowly. Business
relationships needed to be reestablished, and fleets needed to be built up
again.
This monograph provides several accounts of the difficulties individuals and
firms faced in establishing an export and import business. Assistance from the
governments in terms of trade promotion was basically non-existent. Fostering
trade was up to the firms and merchants themselves and took time and a
willingness to take on risks. Many businessmen failed at this business. Overly
rapid expansion, “long delays in the extension of credit and the transfer of
funds,” competition from British trade, and piracy at sea, were the types of
difficulties merchants typically faced. Mustafa argues that trade eventually
thrived between Hanse and American ports partly because of the commonalties
among merchants in both places. Businessmen in both American and German ports
subscribed mostly to the same practical goal, that of liberal capitalism: they
were interested in laws and practices that promoted their commercial interests.
In the Bremen and Hamburg ports, in particular, the merchant class comprised
the largest interest group and had a lot of control in shaping the political
agenda and actions of their city governments to suit their own commercial
needs.
One of Mustafa’s more interesting findings involves the role of political
institutions in economic development. With the exception of the French
occupation period, trade grew in size and importance in spite of the lack of
strong diplomatic ties between the Hanseatic cities and the United States.
During the 1780s and 1790s the American and Hanseatic governments did little to
promote or interfere with international trade and trade thrived; in the
post-Vienna Congress world, trade again grew without immediate governmental
interference.
In spite of the large flow of trade between the Hanseatic and American port
cities, as a young nation the US concentrated its efforts in setting up
diplomatic relations with the big guns of Europe, namely France, Britain,
Spain, Prussia and Austria. In fact, in the last fifteen years of the
eighteenth-century, the US had very little in the way of trade with Prussia but
spent its limited resources on setting up high-level consulates in the Prussian
capital city of Berlin. In contrast, Bremen and Hamburg received low-level
consuls, mostly merchants interested in enhancing their own individual economic
interests. That in this case diplomacy was not a sufficient or a necessary
condition for the development of international trade should be of note to
economists and historians interested in political institutions. Still, it must
be noted that neither the American nor the Hanseatic governments worked
deliberately to impede or interfere with trade between their respective
countries.
For those interested in reading about the larger issues of the migration
literature, this monograph is better at providing background information for
the study of migration movements. Certainly there are many tales of merchants
moving back and forth across the Atlantic Ocean, but there is little material
about the German emigrants who were not merchants and who may have helped
German merchants make their trips to the US more worthwhile. It might have been
quite valuable for readers if Mustafa had explained more clearly why US-bound
emigrants were not as important in merchants’ and shippers’ profit calculations
in Bremen and Hamburg as they were in ports like London or Rotterdam, as
Marianne Wokeck’s Trade in Strangers describes. By the mid-nineteenth
century Bremen emerged as the main port for Central European emigrants. What
importance did this have for the international trade of goods or vice-versa?
These are issues I wish the author had considered or might consider in the
future.
With this work, Mustafa adds one more important case study to the history of
international trade. This book is relevant to those who study the microeconomic
behavior of merchants, traders and entrepreneurs, an area of great interest
among many economists and historians. Those interested in the political economy
of international trade will also find this work interesting, especially since
it recounts three phases, each with a different set of government policy
conditions.
Simone A. Wegge’s research focuses on migration decisions in
nineteenth-century Europe. Her papers have been published in the Journal of
Economic History, and Explorations in Economic History. Forthcoming
articles will appear in Research in Economic History and the European
Review of Economic History. She recently received a best-dissertation award
at the 2002 International Economic History Association meetings in Buenos
Aires.
Subject(s): | International and Domestic Trade and Relations |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 19th Century |