Author(s): | Dyer, Christopher |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Masschaele, James |
Published by EH.NET (September 2002)
Christopher Dyer, Making a Living in the Middle Ages: The People of Britain,
850-1520. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2002. x + 403 pp. $35.00
(Cloth), ISBN: 0-300-09060-9.
Reviewed for EH.NET by James Masschaele, Department of History, Rutgers
University.
Christopher Dyer’s latest book, Making a Living in the Middle Ages: The
People of Britain, 850-1520 appears as part of The New Economic History
of Britain series published by Yale University Press. The aim of the series
is to offer monographs that are sufficiently scholarly to be taken seriously by
academic historians, but sufficiently accessible to appeal to a broader market
of sophisticated amateurs curious to understand why a small island off the
coast of Europe came to have such an inordinate influence on the history of the
world’s economic development. Dyer, now professor of regional and local history
at the University of Leicester, has achieved this objective by providing a
thorough synthesis of existing literature in a book that is highly readable.
Specialists may come away from the book feeling that he hedged his bets on some
of the more controversial issues in the field, but most readers will find the
book to be a clear and well-articulated account of the medieval British
economy.
Dyer divides the period covered into three eras: from 850 to 1100; from 1100 to
1350; and from 1350 to 1520. The first era was one of vigorous and creative
growth, during which the basic patterns of village life, manorial economy, and
urban geography that would survive beyond the medieval period were put in
place. In making the argument for substantial and influential growth, Dyer
relies heavily on archeological evidence to support the meager written evidence
of the period, and his use of archeology and his arguments for major advances
in economic sophistication in the period are among the most original and
interesting parts of the book. Reginald Lennard once famously remarked that by
1066 England was already an old country. Compared to later medieval periods,
relatively little has been written about the economic history of this early
period, but Dyer makes a convincing case that we need to give more heed to
Lennard’s old saw. Whether one looks at settlement patterns, at the exchange
economy, or at the social relations of production, one finds an economy that
looks surprisingly familiar to those better versed in the economic structures
of later centuries.
Dyer divides his second era (1100-1350) into the two phases traditionally
depicted by historians, one of growth in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries
followed by a period of crisis in the early fourteenth century. The growth
phase is presented as a continuation of the first era, essentially a process of
filling in the mold set in the tenth and eleventh centuries. Population grew
quickly, for example, but mostly within settlements founded before the Domesday
Book; similarly, the money supply grew dramatically, but its growth was
associated more with a change in degree of commercial orientation than a change
in kind. Dyer portrays the crisis phase primarily in Malthusian terms, the
consequence of too many mouths feeding from too few acres of land. He expresses
dissatisfaction with several key components of the neo-Malthusian approach
championed by Michael Postan, but like most other economic historians, he finds
it difficult not to view the crisis phase as a consequence of the growth phase.
Dyer’s third era is one of flux, in which different sectors of the economy
experienced different phases of growth, stagnation, and decline, preventing any
easy generalizations. Dyer favors a high estimate of plague mortality, arguing
that a death rate of fifty percent accords well with the evidence. He also
argues for a relatively late date for a return of population growth, offering
1540 as his best guess. Most economic trends in the era are related to this
severe demographic regime. Some towns clearly suffered through the period as
markets shrank and new rivals emerged, but overall Dyer believes that towns
held their own through the period, noting that urban populations comprised
about the same proportion of total population in 1520 as they had in 1300. The
countryside saw considerable conversion from arable to pasture land, as
producers sought to cope with the collapse of the market for cereals in the
fifteenth century. Individual holdings of land increased in size, but many
proprietors of these larger holdings still had difficulty making ends meet. The
principal beneficiaries of the new circumstances of the era were laborers and
smaller landholders, while lords and those who employed labor had the greatest
hurdles to overcome. Dyer insists that collective action by peasants and
laborers, particularly in the Peasants’ Revolt of 1381, was instrumental in
bringing about the redistribution of wealth that favored the lower orders in
the period.
Viewed as a whole, the book has many features to commend it. Dyer’s survey of
existing literature is thorough and his synopsis of the work of other scholars
is intelligent and fair. His inclusion of economic trends in Scotland and Wales
adds refreshing geographical breadth to the work, and often makes for
interesting comparative observations. Reports of archeological fieldwork are
skillfully integrated with documentary sources, and furnish considerable
support for the author’s contention that the material world of medieval
peasants and townspeople was richer and more accomplished than is generally
recognized. (The inclusion of twenty plates and illustrations also is helpful
in this regard.) One is particularly struck by the author’s use of anecdotes
and vignettes to enliven the general description of economic trends. Dyer
insists that individual decision making needs to be set along side impersonal
economic forces to explain why the economy behaved as it did. The story of
deserted villages, for example, is not simply a consequence of the exogenous
influence of disease on society, it is also a consequence of decisions made by
individual peasants to leave particular villages to seek better fortunes
elsewhere. Recapturing the motives, fears, and aspirations of a wide spectrum
of medieval people is not an easy task, and few, if any, medieval economic
historians do it better than Christopher Dyer.
The purpose of a good synthesis is to draw attention to what we don’t know as
well as to highlight what we do know. By adopting relatively broad geographical
and chronological frameworks, Dyer’s book raises a number of issues that beg
for further study. Regional variation is one such example. The author notes on
a number of occasions that pastoral areas differed from arable regions in their
responses to prevailing economic circumstances, but it is far from clear in
these discussions what such shifts mean and how we ought to relate them to the
economy as a whole. Why, for example, did the southwest fare so much better in
the late medieval period than other parts of the country? Similarly, the
author’s reconstruction of population trends over the period raises a host of
questions that defy easy explanations. His reconstruction (seen most readily in
Figure 2 on p. 235) opts for gentle growth from 850-1150, followed by
dramatically faster growth from 1150-1300. Given his emphasis on the structural
continuity between these periods, one is puzzled to explain their fundamentally
different demographic trajectories. One also wonders why late medieval
population levels stagnated for so long. Dyer suggests that both mortality and
fertility issues need to be included in the explanation, but he fails to give a
clear statement of how they ought to be weighted, nor does his treatment of the
subject offer many insights into earlier population dynamics. Perhaps the most
interesting issue raised by his population estimates is the aberrant nature of
the thirteenth century. Dyer’s model suggests that the population of England
ranged between two and three million for every century between the ninth and
sixteenth, except for the thirteenth, when it rocketed to about six million. By
crafting such a fine synthesis of other aspects of the medieval economy, Dyer’s
work suggests that we still have much to learn about the inner dynamics of
medieval demography, as well as about the structural relationships between
population movements, commercial change, and the social relations of production
and income distribution.
James Masschaele is Associate Professor of History at Rutgers University. He
is the author of Peasants, Merchants, and Markets: Inland Trade in Medieval
England (St. Martin’s Press, 1997), and “The Public Space of the
Marketplace in Medieval England,” Speculum 77 (2002).
Subject(s): | Economywide Country Studies and Comparative History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | Europe |
Time Period(s): | Medieval |