Author(s): | Rose, Mary B. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Higgins, David , David |
Published by EH.NET (May 2001)
Mary B. Rose, Firms, Networks and Business Values: The British and American
Cotton Industries since 1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2000. Pp xii + 352). ISBN 0-521-78255-4. ?40.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Dr. David Higgins, University of Sheffield.
The aim of this book is to provide an analysis of the long-term forces shaping
the British and American cotton industries from the eighteenth century through
to 1980. Central to this analysis is the conviction that a multi-disciplinary
approach is required. Although the book covers some of the ‘traditional’
issues which have dominated debates on this industry for example, issues of
technology, industrial organisation and international competitiveness, these
are set against a much broader background which emphasises business culture,
political and legal frameworks, the importance of local and regional
communities and economies, family businesses, interlocking directorships and
the pattern and growth of domestic and foreign markets.
The importance of this wider background is established from a very early stage
in the book. It is probable that the biggest question of all which has
dominated debates on the comparative performance of these two industries is
whether the performance of the British cotton industry would have been
enhanced by adoption of ‘American’ technology and patterns of industrial
organisation. There has been a strong assumption, championed by Chandler and
Lazonick in particular, that ‘American’ means ‘best’. However, argues Rose,
if it can be shown that cotton textile firms in America also experienced
difficulties, despite the presumed advantages of their technology and
organisational form, then it will be hard to sustain the idea that British
cotton textile firms could have avoided their twentieth century difficulties
merely by using American methods (p.2).
The ensuing discussion is rightly critical of any attempt to apply American
methodologies to industries outside the U.S. Much more importantly, though,
is the fact that an alternative line of enquiry is suggested. Comparative
advantage can be determined by scale, technology and industrial organisation
but, equally, it can also be determined by the quality of information flows,
the accuracy of business expectations and the speed and effectiveness with
which businessmen are able to co-ordinate themselves in order to protect
their common interests by, for example, lobbying government. It was in these
crucial areas that Dr. Rose is able to explain the divergent paths taken by
the British and American cotton textile industries.
Broadly speaking, the book is arranged chronologically. Following an
introduction in which the importance of business culture and networks is
spelled out, the book divides into two parts. Part I, which comprises
chapters 2-5, discusses the ways in which the British and American cotton
industries developed during the period 1750-1860. Institutional developments,
especially the emergence and growth of family firm networks, are shown to have
been of much importance in determining the values and attitudes of cotton
businessmen in the two countries. Part II, which comprises chapters 6-8,
analyses the strategic responses made by these businessmen between 1860 and
1980.
Throughout the book the importance of business networks and their consequences
for the very different paths taken by the two industries is carefully
established. In the early stages of the industrialisation process, both
countries shared a common technology. However, Lancashire had the benefit of
proto-industrialisation which ensured that there existed very well-developed
commercial and financial networks, particularly with London finance houses,
together with a large pool of skilled workers. The American industry, by
contrast, was considerably less fortunate. Not only did it lack a comparable
network of commercial and financial institutions and a pool of skilled workers
but also, as a British colony until the War of Independence (1763-1783), it
incurred the unfavourable effects of the Navigation Acts. While the different
nature of resource constraints provides some clues to the divergent nature of
the growth of the American cotton textile industry so too did the wider
political and legal framework, especially intervention by state governments to
foster local industry.
These initial differences between the two industries were quickly accentuated.
For both industries the family firm was a predictable response to
uncertainty. However, whereas most family firms remained small-scale
partnerships throughout much of the nineteenth century in Lancashire, in
America, the corporation became a more widely used form for family businesses.
This divergence in corporate form, together with differences in the degree of
vertical specialisation can both be explained by differences in the complexity
of the supporting infrastructure – itself a product of earlier development.
Whereas Lancashire was to cater increasingly for diverse foreign markets which
required high levels of commercial expertise – and therefore even greater
levels of specialisation, the major textile cities, first in the Northern
states and then in the Southern states of America, had a much greater
dependency on the domestic market. The consequence of this was that the
supporting infrastructure of commercial and financial networks in the two
industries differed. In turn, these differences fostered even greater path
dependency.
Differences between the two industries in their business organisation were
mirrored by differences in labour relations. The crucial role of
sub-contracting in mule spinning was to decline much quicker in America than
in Lancashire. This had obvious implications for the whole issue of
management-worker relations, and labour productivity. Greater reliance on
inter-locking directorships as exemplified by the Boston Associates, meant
that American cotton firms were better able to act collectively in labour
disputes compared to their Lancashire counterparts.
The clear message which comes through from Part I of the book is that the
differing profiles of the British and American cotton industries by 1914 had
little, if anything, to do with institutional rigidities and everything to do
with very different competitive processes. These processes, in turn, were
generated by a much more complex interplay of forces than has previously been
given credence.
Part II of the book extends the analysis from 1860 to 1980. It was within
this period, especially the post-1914 period, that the differences between the
two industries became especially pronounced. In her introduction Rose states
that two issues were to be of continuing importance for the different paths
taken by these two industries: the effectiveness of collusive agreements, and
the strength of the respective networks in lobbying government (p.11). On the
first point, it is the similarities and not the differences between the two
industries which is most apparent. During the interwar years in particular,
both industries suffered from excess-capacity and over-production. Both
industries adopted defensive measures and, in both cases, fragmentation and
disunity were the outcome. In Lancashire, a common policy on short-time
working and price maintenance was continuously undermined by the refusal of
firms in prosperous sections of the industry to sacrifice profits in order to
aid those firms in the most depressed sections. Similar splits appeared in the
American industry, with firms in the North experiencing very serious problems
while those in the South appear to have done comparatively well.
However, it is on the second point, especially in the post-1945 period, that
the differences between the industries could not have been more marked: the
Lancashire industry practically vanishes whereas the American industry,
although experiencing decline in the face of growing import penetration, does
comparatively well. A key reason for this difference was the greater
effectiveness of American firms gaining government support to limit imports
compared to Lancashire firms.
Overall, this is a substantial piece of critical writing which succeeds in
highlighting the very complex range of forces determining the different paths
taken by the two industries. Although some readers may baulk at the price of
?40 for a book which admits it relies heavily on secondary literature, this
should not detract from the fact that the book is both a successful piece of
comparative business history in its widest sense and a successful synthesis of
the literature.
Dr. David Higgins is a Senior Lecturer in Economics, based in the Management
School. He has written extensively on the British textile industries, as well
as on British business generally. His most recent work includes two articles
(with Sue Bowden and Steve Toms, respectively) on the Yorkshire woollen
industry and Lancashire cotton industry published in the Journal of Industrial
History. He is also working on a detailed analysis of British corporate
performance, 1945-90.
Subject(s): | Markets and Institutions |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |