Author(s): | Foreman-Peck, James Federico, Giovanni |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Fauri, Francesca |
Published by EH.NET (May 1, 2000)
James Foreman-Peck and Giovanni Federico, European Industrial Policy: The
Twentieth-Century Experience. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999. xvi +
466 pp. $105 (cloth), ISBN: 0-19828998-7.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Francesca Fauri, Professor of Istituzioni Economiche
Europee, Faculty of Political Sciences, University of Bologna in Forl?.
The aim of this multi-authored volume is to contribute to an understanding of
European industrial policy, broadly interpreted, by introducing an historical
perspective. The collection of case studies allows the reader to become
familiar with the differences among countries, and the remarkable continuity
within countries, of European national industrial policies.
The book analyses the industrial policies of four broad groups of countries:
the largest Western European states – Britain, France, Germany and Italy – a
group of small, but highly productive nations – Sweden, the Netherlands,
Belgium and Ireland – three states with a long tradition of state industrial
regulation: Spain, Portugal and Greece, and finally the case of Russia, a huge
economy with a deep-rooted tradition of centralized decision making and state
intervention.
British industrial policy from the nineteenth century was characterized by
economic liberalism, and despite the greater industrial role of the government
after the First World War, it clung to the liberal precepts of minimum state
expenditure and ‘self-regulation’ during the inter-war period. It was only
after 1945 that the Labour government took a much more interventionist
stance-nationalizing industries such as the coal industry, gas, electricity and
railways and adopting a variety of measures including import controls and
industrial subsidies at levels unknown in the past. In the 1980s, the state
reversed to more market-oriented industrial policies: it abandoned state
ownership and direction of industry, radically improving the performance of
British economy (even though the author claims that the redirection of economic
activity was not necessarily ideal and skill and learning deficiencies began to
emerge).
The French claim to have invented the concept of industrial policy and, as a
matter of fact, since Colbert, the idea that productive capacity can be
increased by state aid has never been abandoned by French governments.
Curiously enough, the chapter on Germany is titled “The Invention of
Interventionism,” contending with the French for the primacy. The first and
most important industrial policy instruments used by the German government
since the 1880s have been tariffs and subsidies. In this case economic
performance has shown that state interventionism and a positive economic trend
are not incompatible at all. Also the Italian state has a long-standing
tradition of intervention, progressively shifting its range of interest from
railways, tariffs and public procurements to bailouts, planning regulation,
subsidization and the use of state-owned enterprises. Albeit, not with German
results, being in the words of the authors “much less effective than it may
have been given the large resources allocated to industrial promotion.”
Small states such as Sweden, the Netherlands, Belgium and Ireland, all
experienced, though in different historical periods, state attempts to
influence industrial growth, usually ranging from rare selective interventions
(protection, subsidies, nationalization) in the past, to general efforts to
facilitate and stimulate industrial growth in more recent times. The
Netherlands is a case in point: arguably the most liberal country in Europe
since its creation in the sixteenth century, between 1948 and 1963 the
government actually intervened in support of declining industries as had never
done before (or has done since).
Spain, Portugal and Greece, three latecomers in the industrialization process,
all present, with different degrees of intensity, a key state role in the
promotion of industrial development. Spain, as the other two, was characterized
by a long-term presence of an authoritarian government, but it was the only one
to combine authoritarianism with a political ideology of intense and
large-scale industrialization. Yet, results were meager: the state
interventionist approach proved not very efficient, supporting the
implementation of a rigid system of import substitution that soon became not
only superfluous, but harmful to overall economic growth.
Russia is the utmost example of industrial policies with maximal state
intervention, at least until the 1990s. During the Tsarist peacetime economy
(1890-1913) the state promoted the development of heavy and defense industry in
order to remedy the technological backwardness of the country. The main
beneficiaries of Tsarist industrial policies were the railway, engineering,
iron, steel and defense industries, with much of the burden falling on the
agricultural sector as a result of tax policies. After the New Economy Policy
interval (1921-27) in which the Bolshevik policy-makers tried to reverse the
policy of nationalization by privatizing small industrial enterprises,
industrial policy in the Stalinist era became highly centralized, the state
owned all productive assets and quantity-oriented plans were utilized as the
main coordination mechanism. State planning was retained as the key industrial
policy instrument until 1992 when economic decision-making started being
decentralized to banks, firms and regions and Russia started its difficult
transition to a market economy. Yet, historical traditions are likely to
influence the pattern of industrial organization and policies that Russia will
develop in the future.
The introduction of a cultural theory of industrial policy in the last chapter
helps explaining why European industrial policies show different degrees of
state intervention. Inter-country differences in the propensity to intervene
also depend on the dimension of trust: industrial policy requires an adequate
degree of trust to succeed.
Surely this volume has two great merits: it provides a collection of case
studies constructed along the same line of discussion themes, thus facilitating
comparative analysis, and it offers a synthesis of a great deal of literature
unavailable in English. Undoubtedly, the book has fulfilled its task of
rendering the future writing on the history of European industrial policy more
manageable.
Francesca Fauri is author of “A Comparative Analysis of Italian and British
Management before World War II” in Vera Zamagni and Lars Engwall, editors,
Management Education in Historical Perspective (Manchester University
Press, 1999) and “Economic Miracle and Italy’s Chemical Industry: A Missed
Opportunity” in Enterprise and Society (forthcoming, summer 2000). She
is currently working on a book on “L’Italia e l’integrazione economica europea
(1947-2000).”
Subject(s): | Economic Planning and Policy |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | Europe |
Time Period(s): | 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII |