Author(s): | Temin, Peter |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Meyer, David R. |
Published by EH.NET (August 2000)
Peter Temin, editor, Engines of Enterprise: An Economic History of New
England. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000. vii + 328 pp.
$24.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-674-00099-4.
Reviewed for EH.NET by David R. Meyer, Department of Sociology, Brown
University.
New England has been subjected to more economic history studies than any other
region, except the South, but coherent explanations of long-term change remain
scarce. Breadth of colonial-period coverage contrasts with idiosyncratic case
studies of nineteenth-century towns, firms, and industries; and seemingly
obvious explanations of New England’s economic travails during the twentieth
century resting on false assumptions. This book helps rectify these gaps in our
knowledge and points to future research. The essays, a result of a conference
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, intend to provide a survey of New
England’s economic history and an intellectual rationale for the Bank’s
creation of a New England economic history museum. Most contributors draw on
their previous New England research or on their expertise with themes that are
applicable to New England; thus, essays are reflective and synthetic, rather
than original.
Several themes — comparative advantage, agglomeration economies, technical
change, and culture — run through the essays, according to Temin’s
introductory chapter, but they serve mostly as reference points for subsequent
narratives. Margaret Newell explains the economic success of colonial New
England as an outcome of an imported culture that valued work, thrift, success,
and consumption. This culture combined with the use of government to support
the common good; the inheritance of Native Americans’ capital investments in
land; an aggressive shift into commercial services and supplying Caribbean
slave economy; and capital investment in agriculture and manufacturing. This
created numerous economic actors (wholesalers, retailers, farmers,
manufacturers) who were poised to contribute to post-colonial development.
Winifred Rothenberg covers the period up to the 1830s and argues that New
Englanders’ value system supported business enterprise. Farmers were swept into
a market economy as price signals increasingly governed decision-making; they
raised productivity, reduced fertility, accumulated capital that was
transferred to commerce and manufacturing, and created markets to efficiently
employ labor. Rural economic transformation set the stage for industrial
growth, especially in cotton textiles. Peter Temin traces rapid
industrialization of New England during 1830-1880, and he attributes it to the
protective tariff that allowed the cotton textile industry to grow and to the
large supply of women, not employed intensively in agriculture, who were
available for factory work. The American System of Manufactures, based on
interchangeable parts, emerged from government armories, which became leaders
in the machine tool industry. Firms with access to these innovations
capitalized on them to become leaders in machinery.
The standard view posits that New England drifted into decline during
1880-1940, because its top industrial sectors of textiles and shoes were not
leaders in the new industrial economy based on consumer and producer durables,
but Joshua Rosenbloom demonstrates errors in that interpretation. Relative,
followed by absolute, decline in New England’s old industries was compensated
by a shift into services and growth of machinery, machine tools, and
instruments, that were part of the emerging industrial economy. Consequently,
per-capita income levels remained 20 to 30 percent above the national level.
That success helps explain New England’s transformation from manufacturing to a
knowledge-based economy — as Lynn Browne and Steven Sass document. Labor
supplies adjusted to economic cycles through in- and out-migration, maintaining
wage levels, and industries shifted, coincident with national manufacturing
changes, from aircraft engines and electronics to minicomputers and instruments
to services (computer, financial, health care). New England’s leadership in
higher education supported this transition to a knowledge-based economy.
The last chapter, in the form of three vignettes, includes reflections on New
England’s economy. Bernard Bailyn highlights the critical boost that Caribbean
and southern slave economies gave to its growth during the colonial period;
Merritt Roe Smith reiterates his research theme that government armories were
critical to its industrialization; and Paul Krugman posits that the directions
of its future economy are indeterminate.
The essays link together sequentially, and, as importantly, thematically, and
major points provide building blocks for the next essay. This is a tribute to
Temin’s editorial skills and guidance. Therefore, readers can consider
questions that span longer time frames, such as the role of education, capital
investment, or industrial innovation. And, perplexing incongruities become
apparent, such as: how were new industries (instruments, aircraft engines)
funded and nurtured coincident with substantial decline in a large share of the
industrial base (textiles, shoes)?
Although the writers reflect on previous research and synthesize it, they
succeed in stimulating fascinating questions for future research. Newell’s
argument that New Englanders successfully built a prosperous economy on trade
services, finance, and production of high value-added products for exports
challenges standard views that regional economies are better off with an export
staple that is widely demanded in external markets. Rather than New Englanders
being forced to adapt to no staples, they grasped opportunities to move into
sophisticated services with high returns on investment, and they built skills
in trade and finance that were less susceptible to competition than staple
exporters, who always faced competition from new, better production areas.
The essays coverage of industry, especially in the nineteenth century, point to
the continuing conundrum of New England industrialization. Rothenberg has slain
the argument that poor agriculture left people with no alternative but to enter
manufacturing. Instead, prosperous farmers accumulated capital that was, in
part, transferred to industry. Nevertheless, we are left with few factors – a
large supply of women not employed intensively in agriculture and government
funding of armories — as reasons why New Englanders grasped industrial
leadership during the nineteenth century, especially before 1880. These are
thin reeds to explain industrialization. New England was not the only eastern
region with large supplies of women not employed intensively in agriculture;
New York and Pennsylvania had similar areas, but their textile and shoe
industries were dwarfed by New England’s. The American System of Manufactures
based on interchangeable parts was not important until late in the nineteenth
century, yet how does one explain widespread development of New England’s metal
manufactures outside the arms sector from 1840 to 1880? While armories were
important, it is not clear that they were pivotal — many private firms had
leading mechanics who did not serve in armories, and even if they went to
armories, they also brought their technical skills. Providence area machine
shops trained many of America’s leading mechanics, but their links to armories
were episodic at most. The large scale of textiles and shoes, and to lesser
extent, machine tools and machinery, obscure growth of other industries such as
jewelry, brass, hardware, clocks, and rubber. Explanation of New England
industrialization must account for them. That effort will broaden
identification of factors that contributed to industrial success. This approach
also provides a better base for explaining, as Rosenbloom argues, resiliency of
New England’s economy even with massive industrial decline during 1880-1940,
and the capacity to shift into new industries after 1940 that Browne and Sass
document, but only explain tentatively.
Many articles and books have covered the post-1945 decline of New England, and
often they have had the facts and explanations wrong. This collection
identifies some factors missing in previous studies, but it leaves important
questions unanswered. Tempting targets for research include tracing links among
machinery, instruments, telecommunications, and early computers. They had deep
roots in the late nineteenth century, but the threads that bind them up to the
1970s remain obscure. Financial services have emerged as a major part of the
New England economy, yet that sector has a rich heritage that continued to
build, not only standard banking and insurance, but also venture-capital firms
and investment management, some of whom go back decades. The essayists
highlight the importance of New England’s educated labor force and its capacity
to move into new economic sectors. Briefly touched on, but awaiting more
research, is the fact that New England contains the nation’s greatest
collection of leading liberal arts colleges and universities, providing
education that has been touted as core to the new knowledge-based economy. As
Krugman notes, change is not predictable. Nevertheless, these essays
demonstrate that the New England economy has maintained strong links to its
past, as well as idiosyncratically departing in new directions. Its
specialization in liberal arts education may suggest some predictability to the
future — precise economic specialization may be uncertain, but labor force
adaptability and the capacity to enter new, leading sectors may be predictable.
David R. Meyer is author of Hong Kong as a Global Metropolis, Cambridge
University Press, 2000. He is completing a book about the
agricultural-industrial transformation of the eastern United States during the
antebellum period.
Subject(s): | Economic Development, Growth, and Aggregate Productivity |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | General or Comparative |