Author(s): | Smith, Mark M. |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Irwin, James R. |
Published by EH.NET (July 1, 2000)
Mark M. Smith, Debating Slavery: Economy and Society in the Antebellum
American South. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998. xii + 117 pp.
$39.95 (hardback), 0-521-57158-8; $11.95 (paperback), ISBN: 0-521-57158-8.
Reviewed by James R. Irwin, Department of Economics, Central Michigan
University.
This book is something between a textbook and an interpretative monograph. It
is part of the Economic History Society’s series, “New Studies in Economic and
Social History.” As the back cover explains, “This series provides a concise
and authoritative guide to the current interpretations of key themes in
economic and social history. Each book in the series summarizes the significant
debates and advances in a major field of study. … The books … are intended
for students approaching a topic for the first time, and for their teachers.”
Based on my own experiences as both student and teacher, I must confess that I
am not a fan of this sort of book. I suppose that giving students just a small
taste of the historical feast could whet their appetites and entice them to dig
in heartily. But I suspect that for most students and many teachers, such books
are a substitute for reading and thinking about history. To summarize my
personal bias: if history is a banquet, then books like this are Spam (at best)
or Olestra (at worst). Having acknowledged that bias at the outset, I’ll try to
put it aside and review Debating Slavery on its own terms.
The book has seven chapters, as well as a preface and bibliography. The first
chapter offers an overview of some of the history and historiography of
Southern slavery. The final chapter attempts a synthesis. Each of the middle
five chapters summarizes and discusses an aspect of antebellum southern
society. The book would have been more accurately titled Debating the Slave
South, rather than Debating Slavery. It does not have a narrow focus
on slavery, but instead covers competing views on many of the big issues in the
social and economic history of the Antebellum South. One major field it does
not deal with is “political” history, thus Whigs and Democrats are not in the
index, nor are Potter, Cooper, Thornton, and Barney (to name just a few who
excited students in decades past). Instead, the chapters lay out debates in
social history and economic history. The social history tends to revolve around
Genovese’s work, and the economic history tends to revolve around Fogel and
Engerman’s. Especially with the social history, Smith demonstrates an admirable
command of the vast literature from which he samples.
In many ways, the Preface and Chapter 1 provide a strong introduction to the
book. The Preface might get students thinking about the nature of freedom and
differences between democracy and capitalism. Chapter 1 starts with a useful
overview of the history of the slave South from colonial times to the Civil
War. However, there follows an effort to suggest that most views of the slave
South can be can be assigned to one of two camps. One, which Smith associates
with Genovese and others, sees the South as “a non-capitalist, unprofitable,
and largely inefficient society.” The other, which Smith associates with Fogel
and Engerman, Oakes and others, “argues the opposite.” I think this a misstep,
because two camps cannot contain the rich variety and subtlety in the
scholarship on the antebellum South.
Chapter 2 addresses competing views of slaveowners, with an emphasis on
planters (typically, those with twenty or more slaves). The key issue Smith
tackles here is whether planters were “non-capitalist” (Genovese) or
“capitalist” (Fogel and Engerman, Oakes). Much of the discussion here turns on
competing perspectives on the economics of slavery which are developed more
fully in Chapter 5 and 6. Students would have been better served if those
chapters had come first, introducing students to two key questions: “Was
slavery profitable to planters?” and “How did it affect economic development?”
Then they could learn that everyone now agrees that the answer to first
question is “usually” (subject to geographic and temporal variation), and that
most of us are still arguing about the second. Then students could tackle the
implications of those economic questions for the more slippery questions of
planter mentalite and the nature of southern white society. Thus, before
working on the question of “capitalist or not?” students would know that
slaveowners got rich off of their slaves and that the southern slave economy
did not industrialize. Then they could grapple with the interpretive questions
such as the distinction between “acquisitive” and “capitalistic.”
With the different organization, students would have an easier time figuring
out that Genovese’s fundamental insights are consistent with evidence that
slaves worked hard and masters profited thereby. Paternalism can help us to
understand why the people worked hard. As it is, Smith attributes to Genovese’s
Roll, Jordan, Roll the view of the slave South as “a plantation society
headed by masters anxious to make money from their investment but unable to do
so because of the paternal relationship they had created with their slaves” (p.
22). Each of us is free to read Roll, Jordan, Roll as she/he sees fit;
but I don’t recall that the planter aristocrats described there were “unable to
make money” from their slaves. More generally, I think Smith makes a strategic
mistake by adopting the dichotomy capitalist or not, because although the term
capitalist may be rich in connotation, there is no agreement on what it means.
The very question “capitalist or not?” can easily distract us from the
fascinating similarities and contrasts between the South and North. This is not
to suggest that Smith invented the debate, but to lament that he did not
reformulate it at the start.
Chapter 3 (“Yeoman and nonslaveowners”) follows the convention in southern
social history (since the 1980’s) that treats small-scale slaveowners (with as
many as five slaves) and non-slaveowning farmers as a single class, the
“yeomen.” Faithful to that literature, Smith does not question whether the
distinction between slaveowner and non-slaveowner really was less important
than that between planter and less affluent white farmers; and he does not
attempt to assign them to the two camps identified in Chapter 1. Smith gives
the impression that there is a consensus that the yeomanry had and preserved
aspects of a “traditional, premarket mentality.” I cannot dispute that, but it
will lead me to revisit the literature and see for myself. Finally, Smith
shares a valuable insight when he notes that “much of the work on the southern
yeomen tends to cast the southern planter class in a market-oriented light” (p.
40).
Chapter 4 (“Slaves”) explores various views on slave work and culture. This
chapter returns to the capitalist non-capitalist dichotomy, sometimes usefully.
There is interesting attention to the links between work and culture, and to
variations over time and across space. On my reading, there is surprisingly
little attention to some major issues, for example, the slave family, African
carry-overs, and religion. There is also surprisingly scant attention to the
material conditions of black life (but there is some attention to slave diets
is the chapter that follows). I do not recall any attention to Fogel and
Engerman’s repeated claims that slaves’ material conditions were “better than
what was typically available to free urban laborers at the time” (as Fogel put
it in Without Consent or Contract, New York: Norton, 1989, p. 391). Nor
to the opposing perspective suggested by Steckel’s arresting finding that the
infant mortality rate of antebellum slaves was as ‘dreadfully’ high as in the
poorest urban slums of India in the twentieth century. There is much attention
given to relatively recent scholarship on the “slave’s economy,” fostering the
view that slaves had significant amounts of “time to call their own” when they
could produce goods (of their own) for consumption or sale. Faithful to the
literature, Smith does not dwell on the scanty empirical basis of studies of
the “slave’s economy,” nor on the extent to which masters were simply making
slaves provision themselves. The chapter includes a misleading rendering of an
example from Fogel and Engerman (p. 53). They describe incentive bonuses that
were given to entire families, but Smith’s account implies that such sizable
bonuses were given to individual slaves.
As noted above, Chapter 5 (“The profitability of slavery as a business”) and
Chapter 6 (“The profitability of slavery as a system”) tackle the economics of
slavery. These are not the strongest chapters in the book. Chapter 5 looks at
slavery at the level of the individual farm and plantation. It takes much too
long to come to a conclusion on the profitability issue, and then, it fails to
clarify the consensus that exists: typically, Southern slaveowners made money
off of their slaves (and to be more precise, they could expect to earn about as
much from investing in slaves as in alternative assets). There is too much
attention to long-outdated sections of Genovese’s Political Economy of
Slavery, and virtually no attention (i.e. too little) to key debates
between Fogel and Engerman and their neoclassical critics. Arguably, the single
most important finding of Fogel and Engerman was that a given amount of labor,
capital, and land produced about one-third more income when it was it was
organized in a single slave plantation than when it was organized in a number
of smaller farms (put technically, that the relative efficiency of plantation
slavery was about one-third greater than smaller scale farms). In their view,
the greater efficiency of plantation slavery resulted from the intense,
arduous, and coordinated labor-effort that could be forced from slaves working
in gangs. Other neoclassical economists have disputed these views, with gusto.
The failure to take up this issue leaves a huge gap in the presentation of this
aspect of the economics of slavery. That said, I think that the responsibility
for the gap lies more with economic historians, than with historians; and more
with all of us, than with Smith. Probably Smith’s omission of the issue is
faithful to the history literature, but not to the economic history literature.
Chapter 6 finds Smith on more solid ground. He cites much of the relevant
literature to identify the crucial questions that are still unresolved: why
were industrialization and urbanization so limited in the South compared to the
North? He falters a bit in his discussion of Fogel and Engerman’s evidence of
growth in southern per capita incomes in the period 1840-60. Smith relies on
Ransom to suggest that the numerous non-slaveholders “who were only marginally
involved in cotton” did not experience economic growth (p. 85). Ransom’s
argument implies a major shift in the distribution of southern income in the
period 1840 to 1860; this is an interesting possibility, but currently there is
not much evidence for it. Also, Smith makes a common mistake when he says (p.
85) that world cotton demand “dropped after 1860.” It was the “growth rate of
cotton demand” that dropped (according to Wright). More generally, the chapters
on the economics of slavery would have been better if they had included some
international comparisons, and some attention to the economic consequences of
emancipation.
The last chapter offers a sort of synthesis, identifying points of potential
consensus, and suggesting “New directions” for future research. It offers
perhaps the most contentious claim in the book; Smith states “an important but
rarely articulated truth: the need and the way to reconcile the apparently
competing schools of thought is probably best achieved not through more
empirical research but through greater theoretical consideration” (p. 89).
Coupled with the claim (at the start of the chapter) that “we know an awful lot
about virtually every aspect of slave culture, the southern economy, and
planters’ ideology” (p. 87), a reader might accuse Smith of calling for a
retreat from the archives. More generally, the last chapter may be a problem
for many students. It finds some common ground among competing perspectives,
focussing mostly on Genovese and Oakes. However it draws heavily on Marx and on
Marxian theories which may not be comprehensible to most students.
The bibliography is wide-ranging and interesting to peruse, but referring to it
while reading was inconvenient, because the entries are grouped according to
chapter. Generally, it is a well-crafted work, even if computer spell-checking
is evident at times (e.g. “none the less” (p. 11), Barrington “Hoore” Jr. (p.
112)). An index also is provided, which will help students to zero in on
authors of interest. As is often the case, perusing the index can be
interesting. For example, I was reminded of both the competence of Smith’s
coverage and the inevitability of omissions when I noticed that the index (and
bibliography) includes Cashin, but not Cash.
In closing, I speculate that writing such a book is an unenviable task; it just
invites criticism. First, there are people like me who think it will just
reduce the number of students who actually read and get engaged in southern
history. Second, every other historian of the South will have her/his own take
on most of the many works that are covered, and most will dispute or dismiss
some aspect of the book. On the other hand, most historians don’t get to write
books for Cambridge University Press. And, I suspect the author enjoyed
feasting at the banquet of scholarship that he drew on for Debating
Slavery.
James R. Irwin’s research concerns the economics of slavery and emancipation
in Virginia and the rest of the South, among other things.
Subject(s): | Social and Cultural History, including Race, Ethnicity and Gender |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | North America |
Time Period(s): | 19th Century |