Author(s): | Dixin, Xu Chengming, Wu |
---|---|
Reviewer(s): | Pomeranz, Kenneth |
Published by EH.NET (August 2000)
Xu Dixin and Wu Chengming, Chinese Capitalism, 1522-1840. Translated by
Li Zhengde, Liang Miaoru and Li Siping. Edited and abridged by C.A. Curwen. New
York: St. Martin’s Press, 2000. xl + 517 pp. $79.95 (cloth), ISBN:
0-333-49732-5.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Kenneth Pomeranz, Department of History, University of
California, Irvine.
This is a translation and abridgment (by about 30 percent) of the first volume
of Xu Dixin and Wu Chengming’s huge three-volume history of Chinese capitalism.
It was originally published in China in the mid-1980s, though much of the work
was done quite a bit earlier (Xu died in 1968). It has now been rendered into
very readable English, and trimmed in a way that retains the real essentials of
the work.
The Chinese version was immediately proclaimed a landmark work, even by people
who disagreed with its sometimes rigid Marxist framework. Since the text now
reaches English readers through a bit of a time warp — and what current
readers may find most valuable may differ from what the authors emphasized — a
few words about its original context are in order. (Some of this context is
provided in the helpful introduction by Peter Nolan and Chris Bramall, who also
suggest ways of relating this book to more recent scholarship, and to more
recent developments in East Asia. In particular, they argue — as would I,
though for somewhat different reasons — that contrasts between Qing China,
Tokugawa Japan, and much of early modern Europe may have been overstated.)
Official Chinese Communist historiography faced a conundrum. If the four stages
of society — slave, feudal, capitalist, socialist — identified by various
authoritative Marxist texts were truly a universal progression, why had China
remained in its “feudal” stage so long? If it had still been “stuck” in that
stage at the time of the Opium War (thus explaining why it was roundly defeated
by relatively small forces from the capitalist world) but had been ready for a
proletarian revolution by 1949, did this mean that capitalism had come from
abroad, and imperialism needed to be accorded a progressive (if painful) role?
To deny that — and to rescue the universality of the Marxist stages — it was
necessary that China had been incubating its own “sprouts of capitalism.”
Various scholars found signs of just that in the late Ming and early Qing; the
failure of these sprouts to blossom fully were then blamed on either Manchu or
British intervention from outside. But there was clearly something ad hoc about
such a solution — if capitalist development had been well underway in the
sixteenth century, why had it been so easily derailed, leaving China to enter
the twentieth century with a small bourgeoisie, tiny proletariat, and much of
what was considered “feudal” society still intact? At least through the 1950s,
the majority of PRC scholars preferred to see Chinese “feudalism” as remarkably
stable, if not quite stagnant, and capitalism as something that came to China
from without.
Xu and Wu sought to cut through the debate by identifying both endogenous
Chinese tendencies toward capitalism and endogenous reasons why they were not
strong enough to “dissolve feudalism” and create a transformation comparable to
what occurred in Northwestern Europe. In a short concluding section, they then
argued that despite the limitations of China’s pre-1840 “embryonic capitalism,”
its development is crucial to understanding what they see as an accelerated
growth of capitalism after 1840, when the economic stimulus and socio-political
disruptions of imperialism were added to endogenous forces. But since we
already have a fairly large literature on the post-1840 period (some of which
builds on material unavailable to Xu and Wu), most readers will find the
material on late Ming and early Qing the most useful part of the book.
Xu and Wu’s response to the received wisdom took two separable, though related,
paths. First, they painstakingly collected evidence of the scale of commerce in
late Ming and early Qing society: how much grain, cloth, iron, liquor, and so
on were sold for cash. The results suggested that far too much of the Chinese
economy was commoditized in this period for it to be comfortably characterized
as “feudal,” and that the scale of commercial exchange was continuing to grow
in the late-eighteenth/early nineteenth century. (It should be noted here that
since Xu and Wu were primarily interested in showing the scale of commodity
production in China, they rarely attempted to estimate total output, or the
quantities of goods that were consumed by their producers, bartered, provided
as in-kind payment for services, or traded locally without the participation of
merchants seeking to accumulate capital, rather than peddlers meeting their own
subsistence needs. Thus these estimates are of relatively little use in the
more recent debate over late imperial Chinese standards of living.) A more
recent generation of scholars has since refined many of these estimates with
the help of additional data, and has usually found them to be lower than is
probably warranted. But many of them are still the state of the art for
particular kinds of trade; making them available to those who don’t read
Chinese is a very important contribution. (An unfortunate limitation of this
contribution is that somewhere in the production of the English text, a number
of numbers were reproduced incorrectly — dropping zeros, for instance — which
sometimes makes two calculations [of say, the number of workers involved in an
enterprise and the size of its output] inconsistent. As far as I can tell, none
of these arithmetic errors are in the original; so while readers who cannot
check the original may need help in figuring out which of two conflicting
numbers is correct, they should not conclude from this that Xu and Wu were
generally unreliable.) For many comparativists –particularly those who do not
share the authors’ Marxist viewpoint – these estimates will be the most
valuable part of the book, and the volume’s organization, with many short
clearly labeled chapters, makes it easy to zero in on the numbers provided for
a particular industry.
But Xu and Wu probably felt that their second line of inquiry — a
reconstruction of the forces and relations of production in various sectors —
was even more important. One need not share their assumption that those sectors
in which workers were fully proletarianized (earning a cash wage, owning none
of the tools of production, enjoying full legal equality, etc.) necessarily
represent the cutting edge of historical change (and were most the likely to
experience technological breakthroughs) to profit from their clear and detailed
reconstructions of how particular industries financed production, paid and
monitored laborers, marketed their products, and so on, and of who was involved
in various lines of production at various times. For most industries, the
technological material offered is less detailed than in the enormous volumes by
Joseph Needham and his collaborators, but quite sufficient for an introduction,
and more attentive to describing average (as opposed to best) practices. The
discussion of the social organization of production is skewed toward
enterprises closely tied to the state (a small portion of the economy, but by
far the best documented part), but exemplary in its careful attention to what
the sources actually do (and don’t) say about payment, supervision,
productivity, and various other topics.
In explaining why what they call “embryonic capitalism” was “retarded” in China
— such that it was a real phenomenon, but not one that would radically remake
Chinese society anytime soon — Xu and Wu emphasize two phenomena: 1) the role
of the Chinese state and 2 )the “unity of agriculture and industry”: i.e. the
fact that much handicraft production was carried out by rural people whose
families continued to own or rent some land.
On the first point, they stake out a rather moderate position, arguing that the
Ming and Qing did not encourage commerce, but were not hostile to it except in
certain specific areas and at certain specific times: they single out frequent
restrictions on foreign trade, mining (which it was felt collected too many
unruly young males in a single place) and in certain frontier zones (where it
was feared that rapid commercialization might undermine local customs and lead
to violence that would be expensive to suppress). They also note that in
general, policies were liberalizing during the first half of the Qing, though
they note that they did not approximate true free trade. (Did they anywhere?)
Given the huge size of China’s domestic economy and long-range internal trade,
the intermittent restrictions on foreign trade seem to me probably not crucial,
except insofar as they inhibited access to foreign science and technology; and
both the Japanese example (where quite a bit of “Dutch learning” was absorbed
through a trade window much narrower than China’s) and the speed with which
certain Western crafts were reproduced on the southeast coast of China suggest
to me that freer foreign trade would not have made a crucial difference here,
either. The arguments about mining seem to me more promising, given the ways
that energy problems and shortages of certain metals may have shaped the Qing
economy. Perhaps most impressive in a book written in pre-reform China is the
simple fact that the authors break down the question “Was the Qing state good
for commerce?” into more specific and verifiable pieces, not insisting on a
blanket answer that covers all kinds of trade and industry; in this way, they
remain ahead of what one still encounters in many of the polemics about Chinese
development, European exceptionalism, and so on.
On the second point, Xu and Wu simply take it as axiomatic that a society in
which the same households produce handicrafts and agricultural goods must be
more “backward” than one in which these functions are separated, and that
households of workers with no way to secure any of their subsistence except by
selling their labor will be more ruthlessly driven to do only those things that
create the highest marginal return than those that still have some access to
subsistence not mediated by the market. These both seem to me questionable
assumptions, not only in the light of late imperial Chinese experience, but
that of Tokugawa Japan, various parts of continental Europe, and the booming
economy of contemporary rural China. But if the persistent combination of
farming and handicrafts, and of market-oriented and subsistence activities in a
highly commercialized economy (perhaps one might call it the failure of
proletarianization rather than the failure of capitalism) was not necessarily
the impediment to growth that Xu and Wu suggest, it is nonetheless a phenomenon
worth careful study; and, for anyone who is interested but does not read
Chinese, the mass of material that Xu and Wu have assembled is now available as
an excellent point of departure. By thus widening the range of scholars who can
help us sort this out, this translation renders an important service.
Kenneth Pomeranz is Professor of History at the University of California,
Irvine. His most recent book is The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the
Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton University Press, 2000).
Subject(s): | Economywide Country Studies and Comparative History |
---|---|
Geographic Area(s): | Asia |
Time Period(s): | 19th Century |