EH.NET BOOK REVIEW
Published by EH.NET (Au gust 1998)
Alice Teichova, editor, Central Europe in the Twentieth Century. An
Economic History Perspective. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing, 1997. 192
pp. $68.95 (cloth), ISBN: 1-85928-105-2.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Michael Palairet, Department of Economic History,
University of Edinburgh.
The contributors to this collection of essays were set the task of
critically assessing the post-Communist transitions in Central Europe
within their historical
context. Most of the authors are practicing
economists and economic historians in senior positions in east European
institutions. It is the transitions themselves which mainly preoccupy
them; their sense of economic history is in the majority of cases weakly
developed.
If there is a consistent theme running through the collection, it is
about resistance to change, both by observation and by the inclination
of the authors themselves. One of the (unintended) uses of the book is,
therefore, what it tells us of the attitudes to economic transition, and
policy inclinations of east European academic elites. None of the
contributors want to turn the clock back, but the tone of the book is
set by Teichova’s introductory essay,
an outline of the economic history
of Central Europe, which hankers for an elusive middle way, eschews the
Thatcherist “victory of enterprise culture,” and seeks to discredit
“shock therapy,” while all see the re-building of the social safety net
as prerequisite to successful transition.
The most extreme of these views emanates from Jorg Roesler who provides
no historical retrospect, and extends his sympathies for the “anger”
felt by the east Germans (despite the most generous regional aid
programme in history) and warns of the deepening gulf in attitudes
between the west and east of the country. His ideal for the east would
seem to be west German standards of prosperity linked with perpetuation
of the right to rent-gua ranteed inefficiency.
The other central European contributors are aware of the absence of a
comparably bountiful feeding hand to bite, but form a consensus around
the proposition that reform can only progress at a speed compatible with
the inclinations and comprehension of the political elites.
Pruca describes economic development in pre-war and Communist
Czechoslovakia in terms which differ little from the analyses put out by
the country’s “liberal” establishment in the 1970s and
’80s. He admits
that “discontinuity was needed in many areas,” but proceeds to condemn
the abrupt changes (under Vaclav Klaus) which would “undermine the
consensus of society.” (For “society” read entrenched opinion formers.)
Returning to ”
shock therapy:” All excoriate it, yet none bother to
explain what the term was intended to mean, by its originator (or
populariser) Jeffrey Sachs. They seem to understand “shock therapy” as
implying a regime of ruthless cut-backs, but Sachs was more concerned to
engineer reversals of inflation expectations, and to use mainly
macro-economic tools to impose business discipline on enterprise
decision making, and in the widest sense, to foster the norms of civil
society.
This task was undoubtedly ambitious, but nevertheless urgent, if the
modest wealth of these countries was no longer to be dissipated in
supporting failure, and reallocated to meeting human needs. In Henryk
Szlajfer’s short institutional survey of Poland’s de velopment, he notes
that in 1988, 24 percent of Polish manufacturing industry subtracted
value (if its outputs were measured in world prices). Value subtraction
was probably an even greater problem for the still more ossified
Romanian economy
according to Daniel Daianu, who advocates the outright
closure of the value-subtractors, and the restructuring of unprofitable
enterprises which nevertheless add value. Fine – but this surely is the
crux of the matter – organized, entrenched opinion is in eastern Europe
closely linked with the value subtractor interest, and Daianu comes
close to explaining why. The system promoted the over-expansion of
“soft” sectors, (steel, chemicals, machine building) whose outputs were
near-unsale able, because it was easier to expand them than the “hard”
sectors (agriculture, consumers goods, energy). So these “soft”
leviathans became the leading sectors, politically, as well as
economically. Therefore they and their political allies became the
bastions of resistance to change, and continued to impose an
insupportable rent charge on the rest of the economy.
The economic history of Yugoslavia is described from a Slovenian
viewpoint by Franjo Stiblar, but in rather wooden terms. Retaining a
nostalgic affection for workers self management, despite its admitted
inefficiency, he tells us how many theatres, doctors, and convicted
criminals operated in 1938 and 1989 (why?) but little about the causes
of Yugoslavia’s precipitate economic decline in the 1980s. His essay
contains the usual criticism of Markovic’s “shock-therapy” reform of
December 1989.
The only contribution to address the problem thematically rather than in
a national context is Michael Kaser’s study of property rights and
international indebtedness. He points out that most of these countries
have been structural debtors throughout the century. If borrowing had
been channelled into useful capital formation, this would not have been
unjustified. Czechoslovakia, for example, could have benefited from more
borrowing, not less, but unhappily investment under Communism was apt to
create net negative property, because of the environmental damage
associated with it.
Probably the most interesting study in this book is Fritz Weber’s essay
on the Austrian economy after World War II. Its experience of
reconstruction differed from Germany’s, with state control,
egalitarianism and employment maximization given priority above price
stability (which is why today’s schilling is worth only about a seventh
of a deutschmark). Planning was used as a tool (says Weber) for the
restoration of the market economy.
The analogy held out for transitional central Europe seems clear. All
had elaborate total planning systems. As enterprises consequently had no
experience of marketing, and were accustomed to orienting production and
the allocation of supplies and deliveries around plan directives, these
systems could have provided a transitional tool for re-pricing and
reallocating resources, to simulate to some degree the behaviour of a
market, yet they do not seem to have been accorded this role.
(Alice Teichova (editor) is Emeritus Professor of Econo mic History at
the University of East Anglia, and Honorary Fellow of Girton College,
Cambridge University.)
Michael Palairet is author of The Balkan Economies c.1800-1914
(Cambridge University Press, 1997), and specialist in the micro-e conomic
history of former Yugoslavia.